1 / 22

Guush Berhane , Daniel Clarke, Stefan Dercon , Ruth Vargas Hill and Alemayehu Seyoum Taffesse

Do i nformal risk-sharing groups reduce the challenge of providing weather indexed insurance p roducts? Evidence from a randomized field experiment in Ethiopia. Guush Berhane , Daniel Clarke, Stefan Dercon , Ruth Vargas Hill and Alemayehu Seyoum Taffesse.

aideen
Download Presentation

Guush Berhane , Daniel Clarke, Stefan Dercon , Ruth Vargas Hill and Alemayehu Seyoum Taffesse

An Image/Link below is provided (as is) to download presentation Download Policy: Content on the Website is provided to you AS IS for your information and personal use and may not be sold / licensed / shared on other websites without getting consent from its author. Content is provided to you AS IS for your information and personal use only. Download presentation by click this link. While downloading, if for some reason you are not able to download a presentation, the publisher may have deleted the file from their server. During download, if you can't get a presentation, the file might be deleted by the publisher.

E N D

Presentation Transcript


  1. Do informal risk-sharing groups reduce the challenge of providing weather indexed insurance products?Evidence from a randomized field experiment in Ethiopia Guush Berhane, Daniel Clarke, Stefan Dercon, Ruth Vargas Hill and Alemayehu Seyoum Taffesse The 2012 Research Conference on Micro-insurance Institute for Innovation and Governance Studies (IGS) University of Twente, The Netherlands April 11 – 13, 2012 Authors’ affiliations: IFPRI: Ruth Vargas Hill, Alemayehu Seyoum Tafesse, GuushBerhane Uni. of Oxford: Stefan Dercon (also DFID), Daniel Clarke (also WB)

  2. Introduction • Weather risk remains a major challenge to farming in the developing world. • Thin insurance possibilities. Informal insurance hampered by risk covariance! • Classical information asymmetry problems & high implementation costslimit viability of traditional insurance. • Index-based weather insurance offers new possibilities • However, demand remains invariably low --- basis-risk – a key challenge

  3. Introduction • Steps taken to mitigate basis risk still limited. • In this work, we study how working with local traditional risk-sharing institutions – as Iddirs in Ethiopia - can help mitigate such challenge. • In a carefully designed RFE, we study how some of the basis risk inherent in an index product can be mitigated. • In so doing, we explore the possibilities in which traditional group savings and risk-sharing activities can be harnessed not just to mitigate basis risk but also examine if such mechanism can be strengthened so that they can be resilient in the face of ever changing climatic and environmental challenges.

  4. Research questions • Specifically, we ask the following questions: • 1) Can group contracts mitigate basis risk by increasing side-payments in the event of individual specific bad outcomes? • 2) Do group contracts require ex-ante rules to effectively mitigate basis risk? • 3) What are the mechanisms through which these processes work and what determines the direction of the outcome? • 4) What are the overall welfare effects (results not yet ready)?

  5. Weather index pilot in Ethiopia • Long run pilot—looking at group institutions takes time • first year in 2011, second year piloting now. • 57 Kebeles (3-4 villages) selected around 3 weather stations in Oromia region of Ethiopia --- Shashemene, Dodota and Tibe • Primary interest is to target risk-sharing groups -- conducted a network mapping exercise to ensure selection of villages with low prob. of network overlap between “treatment” and “control” villages. • 110 villages selected: 60 villages randomly selected for treatment & 50 for controls • Initially 150 villages selected, but 40 were dropped due to lack of capacity to market there

  6. Selling to groups vs. individuals, & mandating • 60 treatment villages further split into: • 25 randomly selected to receive INDIVIDUAL contracts • 35 randomly selected to received GROUP (i.e., IDDIR) contracts – groups decided how many policies to buy & they were encouraged to draw-up bylaws as to how to distribute group savings/payouts • These 35 GROUP villages were further split randomly into two groups : • 18 mandated a certain format for the bylaws. • 17 non-mandated but encouraged

  7. Mandated sharing-rules • What did we mandate? • The group establishes regular savings to a common pot; • A 10% of any insurance payout in this group goes to this pot • This pool is disbursed to members that experience idiosyncratic basis risk, at zero interest rate. • Disbursement criteria is discussed and set by the group at the beginning of the year • Members apply for the loan, group follows disbursement rules! • Repayment is enforced by the rules

  8. Provision of savings • Money was contributed by project as “savings” • Research goal: examine how money is disbursed – need to see disbursements – and also show them we keep our words! • Discussing and agreeing on bylaws is a time-consuming process, it helped to have a reason to do this • Disbursement procedures • In July/August Iddirs received a promise of 800 Birr in October on completion of bylaws discussion. • Mandated: 800 Birr on completion of mandated form agreeing to how payment would be spent • Non-mandated: 800 Birr on completion of discussion, form could state that a discussion would be held in the future on how to split payment • Individual villages: In July/August 16 individuals were randomly selected in a public meeting to receive 50 Birr each in October • Total flow of money into the village is the same, but who receives it is different

  9. Insurance Marketing, Sales, and Take-up • Village level meetings and trainings • First to iddir leaders and influential people • Second to everyone in the village – organized through iddirs leaders and village elders • Very few early season (May, June and July) polices were sold • Discounts offered for late season policies (September): • Free insurance in Dodota and Bako Tibe • Price discounts in Shashemene: 40%, 60%, and 80% discounts randomly allocated across villages • 296 policies were sold in Shashemene (134 individuals and 435 Iddir members), about 13% of households

  10. Payouts • September rains were poor in Shashemene – triggered payout! • Insurance payout was made at the end of October in Shashemene. • Free savings payouts were also made at the end of October in all three study sites.

  11. Data • Baseline survey: February –March 2011 • 1760 households in 110 villages (16 households per village) • Follow up survey I: December 2011, 5- 8 weeks after payouts were made • 1734 households in 110 village re-visited (very little attrition, 1.5%) • 138 iddirs in 110 villages • Follow up survey II: February-March 2012 • Follow up survey III: February-March 2013

  12. Baseline characteristics • High incidence of drought: 51% experienced drought shock in last three years • Formal insurance an almost unknown concept: • 10% had heard about traditional indemnity (car, life or health) insurance • No-one had heard of weather or crop insurance before • Also: • Only 21% have heard of what a millimeter is • Only 7% had a bank account • Initial interest in index-type insurance: 87% were interested in a weather indexed insurance policy described to them in the survey • Indications of huge basis risk: only 32% thought rainfall measured at the nearest weather station accurately measured rainfall on their plots

  13. Informal insurance very prevalent: only 5% did not belong to an iddir; 92% belonged to 1-5 iddirs Baseline characteristics

  14. Baseline characteristics Close to 80% of iddirs span within the village

  15. Analysis • We compare outcomes between the control and the following treatment groups: • Individual and iddir • Mandated and non-mandated iddirs • We estimate the ANCOVA for outcome variables of interest with baseline data: • We estimate a difference in outcome equation for outcome variables of interest without baseline data: • Stratification at location (weather station level) so dummies are included for this in all regressions • Randomization at village level, so standard errors are clustered at the village level

  16. Results: can groups be encouraged to reduce basis risk by increasing transfers? • Changed iddir rules • No clear difference between iddirs in “iddir” treatment and “individual” treatment villages • We will see that this is because we are combining mandates and non-mandated iddirs • Changing perceived ability to access cash for emergencies • Households from “iddir” villages are more likely to access cash for 1,000 medical emergency. No more likely to access larger amounts or cash for non-emergent reasons. • Households from “individual” villages perceive themselves as less able to access large (4000 ETB) cash loans. Further investigation needed to answer why this is. • Actual transfers received since payouts (from those who did not directly receive an insurance payout, or “free savings” in individual villages): • Fewer transfers from individuals • More transfers from institutions (including iddirs) – largely from immediately after payouts were made

  17. Results: can groups be encouraged to reduce basis risk by increasing transfers?

  18. Results: are ex-ante rules important in encouraging transfers? • Changed iddir rules • Clear difference between mandated-iddir villages and other villages: mandating changed the rules • Changing perceived ability to access cash for emergencies • Non-mandated iddirs perceive themselves as better able to fund emergencies, but the source of these funds is not iddirs, rather friends or assets. • Mandated iddirs are not more likely to finance medical emergencies, but are more likely to rely on iddirs for the financing of these emergencies. • Actual transfers received since payouts (from those who did not directly receive an insurance payout, or “free savings” in individual villages): • Mandating reduces transfers from individuals, non-mandating does not. • Mandating results in a larger effect on transfers from institutions (but point estimates for mandating and non-mandating are not statistically significant from each other).

  19. Results: are ex-ante rules important in encouraging transfers?

  20. Results: By what mechanisms are transfers increased? • Change of rules for mandated iddirs • Higher insurance demand: • Evidence that demand for insurance was lower in non-mandated iddir villages and higher in mandated iddir and individual villages. • Trust: • Not much change in overall trust (e.g., “most people can be trusted”) as a result of the intervention, perhaps due to longer period needed. • No effect on trust in iddir leaders. • Changing nature of payouts and information: households in iddir villages were: • less likely to have received a payout (esp. non-mandated) • more likely to have reported that the insurance or payout was big enough to help (significant) • more likely to know others that received an insurance payout, or have others know about their insurance payouts (esp. mandated)

  21. Conclusions • Lessons learned: • Local risk sharing groups can be encouraged to make payouts to members in the event of idiosyncratic crop loss. We saw changed rules and increases in institutional payments • Not clear whether mandating helps– it ensures rules are changed, but does it do more than this? • Seems to be some crowding out—transfers from individuals are lower, particularly in mandated iddirs (although increased institutional transfers). • Further analysis needed: • Did the increased institutional transfers reduce basis risk and improve welfare outcomes? • How does this develop in the long-run? • Better understand how this interacts with demand for formal insurance products • Next steps, this season: • Continue with sharing rules and observe an additional season of insurance. • Included a feature to the index – i.e., gap insurance. A carefully designed crop-cutting experiment is added to the index. • A lot of optimism this year – many policies already sold, particularly in area where payouts made last year

  22. Thank you

More Related