1 / 24

The Insurance Value of Medical Innovation

The Insurance Value of Medical Innovation. Darius Lakdawalla Anup Malani Julian Reif USC and NBER University of Chicago University of Illinois. Consider a standard coin toss gamble. Risk matters when evaluating payoffs.

yaron
Download Presentation

The Insurance Value of Medical Innovation

An Image/Link below is provided (as is) to download presentation Download Policy: Content on the Website is provided to you AS IS for your information and personal use and may not be sold / licensed / shared on other websites without getting consent from its author. Content is provided to you AS IS for your information and personal use only. Download presentation by click this link. While downloading, if for some reason you are not able to download a presentation, the publisher may have deleted the file from their server. During download, if you can't get a presentation, the file might be deleted by the publisher.

E N D

Presentation Transcript


  1. The Insurance Value of Medical Innovation Darius Lakdawalla Anup Malani Julian Reif USC and NBER University of Chicago University of Illinois

  2. Consider a standard coin toss gamble Risk matters when evaluating payoffs

  3. Valuing medical technology: Gleevec for treatment of chronic myeloid leukemia Technology may produce “self-insurance” value

  4. Valuing medical technology: Highly Active Antiretroviral Therapy (HAART) for HIV Technology may produce “market insurance” value

  5. Risk-reduction value of technology raises several research questions • How can we define and measure the risk-reduction value of medical technology? • Under what conditions is it appropriate to abstract away from risk-reduction value? • How empirically significant is risk-reduction value over a range of real-world medical technologies? • What are the implications for how we value and pay for different types of medical technologies?

  6. Value of medical technology can be intuitively illustrated in a simple two-good model • Imagine that utility depends on consumption and health for a (weakly) risk-averse consumer • There are two health states – “sick” and “well” – and the risk, , of the “sick” state in which: • Consumption endowments fall to • Health endowments fall to • There exists some medical technology sold at price that raises health in the sick state to

  7. Intuition can be illustrated in a one-good model

  8. Conventional “risk-free” value is the movement along the original expected utility chord Traditional value

  9. Additional “self-insurance” value accounts for the movement up the risk-averse utility curve Self-insurance value

  10. Additional “market insurance” value accounts for the incremental value of financially insuring the technology Market-insurance value

  11. Traditional valuations ignore the “insurance value” Insurance value Traditional value Insurance value is the sum of self insurance and market insurance

  12. Results from theoretical analysis • Three separate components of value: • Traditional Value of Technology • Corresponds to the “risk-free” value • Self-Insurance Value of Technology (SIVT) • Market-Insurance Value of Technology (MIVT) • Accounting for only the traditional valuation causes researcher to underestimate the total value of technology • This underestimate is particularly bad for severe diseases with low quality of life, i.e., high “unmet need”

  13. Empirical framework is based on Cobb-Douglas utility • Consider the two-good version of the model implied by: • measures quality of life, and is consumption • determines the MRS between consumption and health – i.e., the willingness to pay for health improvement • determines the demand for insurance – the higher is , the greater the demand for insurance

  14. Parameterizing the utility function • We pick a baseline value of equal to 0.3 • We calibrate using estimates of risk-aversion • Baseline value of 3 (implies relative risk-aversion equal to 1.6) • We set annual income equal to $50,000 • We obtain measures of price and quality of life from data on cost-effectiveness studies • Uses the “QALY” framework • Quality of life ranges from 0 to 1

  15. “Cost-effectiveness” of technology drives variation in the risk-free and insurance values Simulated estimates of RFVT, SIVT, and MIVT as a function of price. Total = RFVT + SIVT + MIVT. Parameters are = 0.3, =$50,000, = 1, = 0.7, and = 0.1.

  16. Value of health technology is right-skewed

  17. Value of health technology is right-skewed

  18. Insurance value dominated by self-insurance and comparable in magnitude to risk-free value

  19. Providing special reimbursement for treating diseases with high unmet need remains controversial • “[The fund] not only undermines NICE, it undermines the entire concept of a rational and evidence-based approach to the allocation of finite health-care resources.” • “New cancer treatments clearly challenge the cost thresholds set by NICE”

  20. Self insurance value (SIV) is large for diseases with high unmet need

  21. Treating diseases with unmet needs – e.g., cancer – is much more valuable than previously recognized HIV/AIDS Gleevec Alzheimer’s

  22. Policy implications of risk-reduction value • Economic value of health increases may be larger than previously thought • Greater expenditures on health-related research may be worthwhile • Health technology assessment • Risk-reduction value should be incorporated into value assessments • Treatments for diseases with high unmet need are especially undervalued, perhaps by an order of magnitude

  23. Reexamining the role of medical innovation • Policies to promote new health technology also function like insurance reform • Financial markets may have played a secondary role in reducing society’s exposure to health risk • The distributional implications of health technologies have been poorly understood • The poor benefit disproportionately from health risk-reduction (McClellan and Skinner, 2006) • Access to medical technology is a policy substitute for financial redistribution or means-tested health insurance

More Related