Download

Simple Keynesian Model






Advertisement
/ 72 []
Download Presentation
Comments
xue
From:
|  
(1248) |   (0) |   (0)
Views: 296 | Added:
Rate Presentation: 1 0
Description:
Simple Keynesian Model. National Income Determination Three-Sector National Income Model. Outline. Three-Sector Model Tax Function T = f (Y) Consumption Function C = f (Yd) Government Expenditure Function G=f(Y) Aggregate Expenditure Function E = f(Y)
Simple Keynesian Model

An Image/Link below is provided (as is) to

Download Policy: Content on the Website is provided to you AS IS for your information and personal use only and may not be sold or licensed nor shared on other sites. SlideServe reserves the right to change this policy at anytime. While downloading, If for some reason you are not able to download a presentation, the publisher may have deleted the file from their server.











- - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - E N D - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - -




Simple keynesian model l.jpgSlide 1

Simple Keynesian Model

National Income Determination

Three-Sector National Income Model

Outline l.jpgSlide 2

Outline

  • Three-Sector Model

  • Tax Function T = f (Y)

  • Consumption Function C = f (Yd)

  • Government Expenditure Function G=f(Y)

  • Aggregate Expenditure Function E = f(Y)

  • Output-Expenditure Approach: Equilibrium National Income Ye

Outline3 l.jpgSlide 3

Outline

  • Factors affecting Ye

  • Expenditure Multipliers k E

  • Tax Multipliers k T

  • Balanced-Budget Multipliers k B

  • Injection-Withdrawal Approach: Equilibrium National Income Ye

Outline4 l.jpgSlide 4

Outline

  • Fiscal Policy (v.s. Monetary Policy)

  • Recessionary Gap Yf - Ye

  • Inflationary Gap Ye - Yf

  • Financing the Government Budget

  • Automatic Built-in Stabilizers

Three sector model l.jpgSlide 5

Three-Sector Model

  • With the introduction of the government sector (i.e. together with households C, firms I), aggregate expenditure E consists of one more component, government expenditure G.

    E = C + I+ G

  • Still, the equilibrium condition is

    Planned Y = Planned E

Three sector model6 l.jpgSlide 6

Three-Sector Model

  • Consumption function is positively related to disposable income Yd [slide 37 of 2-sector model],

    C = f(Yd)

    C= C’

    C= cYd

    C= C’ + cYd

Three sector model7 l.jpgSlide 7

Three-Sector Model

  • National Income  Personal Income  Disposable Personal Income

  • w/ direct income tax Ta and transfer payment Tr

  • Yd  Y

  • Yd = Y - Ta + Tr

Three sector model8 l.jpgSlide 8

Three-Sector Model

  • Transfer payment Tr can be treated as negative tax, T is defined as direct income tax Ta net of transfer payment Tr

  • T = Ta - Tr

  • Yd = Y - (Ta - Tr)

  • Yd = Y - T

Three sector model9 l.jpgSlide 9

Three-Sector Model

  • The assumptions for the 2-sector Keynesian model are still valid for this 3-sector model [slide 24-25 of 2-sector model]

Tax function l.jpgSlide 10

Tax Function

  • T = f(Y)

  • T = T’

  • T = tY

  • T = T’ + tY

Tax function11 l.jpgSlide 11

Tax Function

T = T’

Y-intercept=T’

slope of tangent=0

T = tY

Y-intercept=0

slope of tangent=t

T = T’ +tY

Y-intercept=T’

slope of tangent=t

Tax function12 l.jpgSlide 12

Tax Function

  • Autonomous Tax T’

    • this is a lump-sum tax which is independent of income level Y

  • Proportional Income Tax tY

    • marginal tax rate t is a constant

  • Progressive Income Tax tY

    • marginal tax rate t increases

  • Regressive Income Tax tY

    • marginal tax rate t decreases

Consumption function l.jpgSlide 13

Consumption Function

  • C = f(Yd)

  • C = C’

    C = C’

  • C = cYd

    C = c(Y - T)

  • C = C’ + cYd

    C = C’ + c(Y - T)

Consumption function c c c y t l.jpgSlide 14

Consumption FunctionC = C’ + c(Y - T)

  • T = T’

    C = C’ + c(Y - T’)  C = C’- cT’ + cY

     slope of tangent = c

  • T = tY

    C = C’ + c(Y - tY)  C = C’ + (c - ct)Y

    slope of tangent = c - ct

  • T = T’ + tY

    C = C’+c[Y-(T’+tY)]C = C’ - cT’ + (c - ct) Y

    slope of tangent = c - ct

Consumption function c c c y t15 l.jpgSlide 15

Consumption FunctionC = C’ + c (Y - T’)

Y-intercept = C’ - cT’

slope of tangent = c = MPC

slope of ray APC  when Y

Consumption function c c c y ty l.jpgSlide 16

Consumption FunctionC = C’ + c (Y - tY)

Y-intercept = C’

slope of tangent = c - ct = MPC (1-t)

slope of ray APC  when Y

Consumption function c c c y t ty l.jpgSlide 17

Consumption Function C = C’ + c [Y - (T’ + tY)]

Y-intercept = C’ -cT’

slope of tangent = c - ct = MPC (1-t)

slope of ray APC  when Y

Consumption function c c c t c c t y l.jpgSlide 18

Consumption Function C = C’ - cT’ + (c - ct)Y

  • C’ OR T’ 

     y-intercept C’ - cT’   C shift upward

  • t 

     c(1-t)   C flatter

  • c 

     c(1-t)  C steeper

     y-intercept C’ - cT’ C shift downward

Government expenditure function l.jpgSlide 19

Government Expenditure Function

  • G only includes the part of government expenditure spending on goods and services, i.e. transfer payments Tr are excluded.

  • Usually, G is assumed to be an exogenous / autonomous function

  • G = G’

Government expenditure function20 l.jpgSlide 20

Government Expenditure Function

Y-intercept = G’

slope of tangent = 0

slope of ray  when Y

Aggregate expenditure function l.jpgSlide 21

Aggregate Expenditure Function

  • E = C + I + G

    given C = C’ + cYd

    T = T’ + tY

    I = I’

    G = G’

  • E = C’ + c[Y -(T’+tY)] + I’ + G’

  • E = C’ - cT’ + I’+ G’ + (c-ct)Y

  • E = E’ + c(1-t) Y

Aggregate expenditure function22 l.jpgSlide 22

Aggregate Expenditure Function

  • E = C’ - cT’ + I’ + G’ + (c - ct)Y

  • E = E’ + (c - ct)Y

    given E’ = C’ - cT’ + I’ + G’

  • E’ is the y-intercept of the aggregate expenditure function E

  • c - ct is the slope of the aggregate expenditure function E

Aggregate expenditure function23 l.jpgSlide 23

Aggregate Expenditure Function

  • Derive the aggregate expenditure function E if T = T’

  • E = C’- cT’ + I’ + G’ + cY

  • y-intercept = C’- cT’ + I’ + G’

  • slope of tangent = c

Aggregate expenditure function24 l.jpgSlide 24

Aggregate Expenditure Function

  • Derive the aggregate expenditure function E if T = tY

  • E = C’ + I’ + G’ + (c-ct)Y

  • y-intercept = C’ + I’ + G’

  • slope of tangent = (c-ct)

Aggregate expenditure function25 l.jpgSlide 25

Aggregate Expenditure Function

  • Derive the aggregate expenditure function E if T = T’ and I = I’ + iY

  • E = C’- cT’ + I’ + G’ + (c + i)Y

  • y-intercept = C’- cT’ + I’ + G’

  • slope of tangent = (c + i)

Aggregate expenditure function26 l.jpgSlide 26

Aggregate Expenditure Function

  • Derive the aggregate expenditure function E if T = tY and I = I’ +iY

  • E = C’ + I’ + G’ + (c - ct+i )Y

  • y-intercept = C’ + I’ + G’

  • slope of tangent = (c - ct+i )

Aggregate expenditure function27 l.jpgSlide 27

Aggregate Expenditure Function

  • Derive the aggregate expenditure function E if T = T’ + tY and I = I’ +iY

  • E = C’- cT’ + I’ + G’ + (c - ct+i)Y

  • y-intercept = C’- cT’ + I’ + G’

  • slope of tangent = (c - ct+i)

Output expenditure approach w t t ty w c c cyd l.jpgSlide 28

Output-Expenditure Approachw/ T = T’ + tYw/ C = C’ + cYd

C

2-Sector

C = C’ + cYd = C’ + cY

Slope of tangent = c = MPC =C/Yd

Slope of tangent = c (1-t) = (1-t)*MPC  MPC

C = C’ - cT’ + c(1-t)Y

3-Sector

C’

C’ -cT’

Y

Slide29 l.jpgSlide 29

I, G, C, E, Y

Y=E

Y

Planned Y = Planned E

Output expenditure approach i i exogenous function l.jpgSlide 30

Output-Expenditure ApproachI = I’ exogenous function

  • E = E’ + (c - ct) Y [slide 21-22]

  • In equilibrium, planned Y = planned E

  • Y = E’+ (c - ct) Y

  • (1- c + ct) Y = E’

  • Y = E’

    E’ = C’ - cT’ + I’ + G’

    k E =

1

1 - c + ct

1

1 - c + ct

Output expenditure approach i i iy endogenous function l.jpgSlide 31

Output-Expenditure ApproachI= I’+iY endogenous function

  • E = E’ + (c - ct + i) Y [slide 27]

  • In equilibrium, planned Y = planned E

  • Y = E’ + (c - ct + i) Y

  • (1- c + ct - i) Y = E’

  • Y = E’

    E’ = C’ - cT’ + I’ + G’

    k E =

1

1 - c - i + ct

1

1 - c - i + ct

Output expenditure approach t t exogenous function i i iy l.jpgSlide 32

Output-Expenditure ApproachT = T’ exogenous functionI = I’ + iY

  • E = E’+ (c + i) Y [slide 25]

  • In equilibrium, planned Y = planned E

  • Y = E’+ (c + i) Y

  • (1 - c - i) Y = E’

  • Y = E’

    E’ = C’ - cT’ + I’ + G’

    k E =

1

1 - c - i

1

1 - c - i

Factors affecting ye l.jpgSlide 33

Factors affecting Ye

  • Ye = k E * E’

  • In the Keynesian model, aggregate expenditure E is the determinant of Ye since AS is horizontal and price is rigid.

  • In equilibrium, planned Y = planned E

  • E = C’ - cT’ + I’ + G’ + (c - ct + i) Y

  • Any change to the exogenous variables will cause the aggregate expenditure function to change and hence Ye

Factors affecting ye34 l.jpgSlide 34

Factors affecting Ye

  • Change in E’

  • If C’I’G’  E’  E Y 

  • If T’C’ - cT’ E’ by- cT’E Y

  • Change in k E / slope of tangent of E

  • If c i   E steeper  Y

  • If c   C’ - cT’  E’  E  Y 

  • If t   E steeper  Y 

Slide35 l.jpgSlide 35

I, G, C, E, Y

Y=E

Y

Slide36 l.jpgSlide 36

I, E, Y

I’

E’ = I’

 I’

Y

Ye = k E E’

Slide37 l.jpgSlide 37

G, E, Y

G’

Y

Slide38 l.jpgSlide 38

C, E, Y

C’

Y

Slide39 l.jpgSlide 39

C, E, Y

T’

C  by -cT’

Y

Slide40 l.jpgSlide 40

I, E, Y

 i

Y

Digression l.jpgSlide 41

Digression

  • Differentiation

  • y = c + mx

  • differentiate y with respect to x

  • dy/dx = m

Expenditure multiplier k e l.jpgSlide 42

Expenditure Multiplier k E

  • Y = k E * E’ E’ = C’ - cT’ + I’ + G’

  • k E = if I=I’ & T=T’+tY

  • k E = if I=I’+iY & T=T’+tY

  • k E = if I=I’+iY & T=T’

1

1 - c + ct

1

1 - c + ct - i

1

1 - c - i

Expenditure multiplier k e43 l.jpgSlide 43

Expenditure Multiplier k E

  • Whenever there is a change in the autonomous spending C’I’ or G’ the national income Ye will change by a multiple of k E.

  • It actually measures the ratio of the change in national income Ye to the change in the autonomous expenditure E’

  • Ye/E’ = k E

Tax multiplier k t l.jpgSlide 44

Tax Multiplier k T

  • Y = k E * ( C’- cT’ + I’ + G’)

  • k T = if I=I’ & T=T’+tY

  • k T = if I=I’+iY & T=T’+tY

  • k T = if I=I’+iY & T=T’

-c

1 - c + ct

-c

1 - c + ct + i

-c

1 - c - i

Tax multiplier k t45 l.jpgSlide 45

Tax Multiplier k T

  • Any change in the lump-sum taxT’ will lead to a change in the national income Ye by a multiple of k T in the opposite direction since k T takes on a negative value

  • Besides, the absolute value of k T is less than the value of k E.

Balanced budget multiplier k b l.jpgSlide 46

Balanced-Budget Multiplier k B

  • G’  E’   E   Ye  by k E times

  • T’  E’   E   Ye  by k T times

  • If G’  = T’  , the change in Ye can be measured by k B

  • Y/ G’ = k E

  • Y/ T’ = k T

  • k B = k E + k T

  • k B = + = 1

1

1-c

-c

1-c

Balanced budget multiplier k b47 l.jpgSlide 47

Balanced-Budget Multiplier k B

  • The balanced-budget multiplier k B = 1 when t=0 & i=0

  • What is the value of k B if t  0 ?

  • If k B = 1 an increase in government expenditure of $1 which is financed by a $1 increase in the lump-sum income tax, the national income Ye will also increase by $1

Injection withdrawal approach l.jpgSlide 48

Injection-Withdrawal Approach

  • In a 3-sector model, national income is either consumed, saved or taxed by the government

  • Y = C + S + T

  • Given E = C + I + G

  • In equilibrium, Y = E

  • C + S + T = C + I + G

  •  S + T = I + G

Injection withdrawal approach49 l.jpgSlide 49

Injection-Withdrawal Approach

  • Since S + T = I + G

  • S  I

  • T  G

  • I > S  T > G

  • I < S  T < G

  • (Compare with 2-sector model)

  • In equilibrium S = I

Injection withdrawal approach50 l.jpgSlide 50

Injection-Withdrawal Approach

  • T = T’ + tY

  • S = -C’ + (1-c) Yd

  • S = -C’ + (1 - c)[Y -_(T’ + tY)]

  • S = -C’ + (1 - c)[Y - T’ - tY]

  • S = -C’ + Y - T’ - tY - cY + cT’ + ctY

  • S = -C’ + cT’ -T’ - tY + Y - cY + ctY

  • S = -C’ + cT’ - (T’ + tY) + Y - cY + ctY

Injection withdrawal approach51 l.jpgSlide 51

Injection-Withdrawal Approach

  • S + T = -C’ + cT’ -(T’+ tY) + Y - cY + ctY +T

  • S + T = -C’ + cT’ + Y - cY + ctY

  • In equilibrium, S + T = I + G

  • -C’ + cT’ + Y - cY + ctY = I’ + G’

  • (1- c + ct)Y = C’ - cT’ + I’ + G’

  • Ye = k E * E’

  • E’ = C’ - cT’ + I’ + G’ [slide 30]

Use the injection withdrawal approach to solve for ye if t t l.jpgSlide 52

Use the Injection-Withdrawal Approach to solve for Ye if T=T’

Fiscal policy l.jpgSlide 53

Fiscal Policy

  • The use of government expenditure and taxation to achieve certain goals, such as high employment, price stability.

  • Discretionary Fiscal Policy

    • Expansionary Fiscal Policy (when Yf > Ye)

    • Contractionary Fiscal Policy (when Yf < Ye)

  • Automatic Built-in Stabilizers

    • Proportional / Progressive Tax System

    • Welfare Schemes

Expansionary fiscal policy recessionary deflationary gap yf ye l.jpgSlide 54

Expansionary Fiscal Policy Recessionary/Deflationary Gap Yf-Ye

Y-line

G’  E’  E  Y

E = E” + (c-ct) Y

E = E’ + (c -ct) Y

G’

Y= k E * E’

Recessionary Gap

Ye

Yf

Expansionary fiscal policy recessionary deflationary gap yf ye55 l.jpgSlide 55

Expansionary Fiscal Policy Recessionary/Deflationary Gap Yf-Ye

Y-line

T’  E’ by -c T’  E  Y

E = E” + (c-ct) Y

E = E’ + (c -ct) Y

-cT’

Y= k E * E’ = k T *T’

Recessionary Gap

Ye

Yf

Contractionary fiscal policy inflationary gap ye yf l.jpgSlide 56

Contractionary Fiscal PolicyInflationary Gap Ye - Yf

Y = E

G’  E’  E  Y

E = E’ + (c-ct) Y

E = E” + (c-ct) Y

G’

Y= k E * E’

Nominal Y>Yf Inflationary Gap

Yf

Ye

Contractionary fiscal policy inflationary gap ye yf57 l.jpgSlide 57

Contractionary Fiscal PolicyInflationary Gap Ye - Yf

Y = E

T’  E’ by -c T’  E  Y

E = E’ + (c-ct) Y

E = E” + (c-ct) Y

-cT’

Y= k E * E’ = k T *T’

Nominal Y>Yf Inflationary Gap

Yf

Ye

Automatic built in stabilizers l.jpgSlide 58

Automatic Built-in Stabilizers

  • Proportional /Progressive Tax System

    • Recession: government’s tax revenue 

    • Boom: government’s tax revenue 

  • The more progressive the tax system, the greater is its stabilizing effect. But there will be greater dis-incentives to earn income

  • With t, k E  With proportional tax, the multiplying effect of a discretionary change in government expenditure G’ reduces

Automatic built in stabilizers59 l.jpgSlide 59

Automatic Built-in Stabilizers

  • Welfare Schemes

  • Unemployment benefits, public assistance allowances, agricultural support schemes

    • Recession: government’s expenditure

    • Boom: government’s expenditure 

  • Again, if the welfare schemes are generous, the incentives to work will be weakened.

Discretionary fiscal policy v s automatic built in stabilizers l.jpgSlide 60

Discretionary Fiscal Policy v.s.Automatic Built-in Stabilizers

  • If the economy is close to Yf, built-in stabilizers are useful as they can stabilize the economy around Yf or potential income level.

  • However, if the economy is far below Yf, discretionary fiscal policy is still necessary (Simple Keynesian model).

  • Another drawback of the built-in stabilizers is they may reduce the speed of recovery as

  • k E  Y = k E * E’

Discretionary fiscal policy l.jpgSlide 61

Discretionary Fiscal Policy

  • Government expenditure G’? Tax T’?

  • Location of effects

  • If a recession is localized in a particular industry  G’

  • Tax cut will have its impact on the entire economy

Discretionary fiscal policy62 l.jpgSlide 62

Discretionary Fiscal Policy

  • Government expenditure G’? Tax T’?

  • Duration of the time lag

    • Decision lag : time involved to assess a situation & decide what corrective actions should be taken

    • Executive lag : time involved to initiate corrective policies & for their full impact to be felt

       tax cut has a much shorter executive lag

Discretionary fiscal policy63 l.jpgSlide 63

Discretionary Fiscal Policy

  • Government expenditure G’? Tax T’?

  • Reversibility of the fiscal policy

    • Government expenditure can easily be increased but are not so easy to cut as the civil servants who have vested interests in the present allocation of government expenditure will resist

    • Tax is easier to be changed as the civil servants who administer income tax is independent of the rate being levied. Of course, voter resistance should also be considered.

Discretionary fiscal policy64 l.jpgSlide 64

Discretionary Fiscal Policy

  • Government expenditure G’? Tax T’?

  • Public reaction to short-term changes

  • A temporary tax cut raises Yd. Households, recognizing this situation, may not revise their current consumption. Instead, they save a large part of the tax cut.

Financing the government budget increasing taxes l.jpgSlide 65

Financing the Government BudgetIncreasing Taxes

  • By increasing taxes, the government transfers purchasing power from current taxpayers to itself

  • Current taxpayers bear the cost

  • If the revenue is spent on some investment project, (current / future) taxpayers may benefit when the project is completed.

  • How about the revenue is spent on transfer payment?

Financing the government budget printing more money l.jpgSlide 66

Financing the Government BudgetPrinting more Money

  • This will create inflationary pressure.

  • Households and firms will be able to buy less with each unit of money. Fewer resources are available for private consumption and investment.

  • Those whose incomes respond slowly to changes in price levels will bear most of the cost of the government activity

Financing the government budget internal debt l.jpgSlide 67

Financing the Government BudgetInternal Debt

  • The government can transfer purchasing power from any willing lenders to itself in return for the promise to repay equivalent purchasing power plus interest in future.

  • Since, repayment of the debt are made from tax revenue, future taxpayers will suffer.

  • However, if the debt raised today is spent on creating capital assets, the burden on future generation will be lighter.

Financing the government budget external debt l.jpgSlide 68

Financing the Government BudgetExternal Debt

  • Borrowing from abroad transfers purchasing power from foreigners to the government.

  • The burden on future generations will once again depend on how the debt raised is used (investment project / transfer payment)

The problems of the simple keynesian multiplier k e l.jpgSlide 69

The Problems of the Simple Keynesian Multiplier k E

  • Y = k E * G’

  • There are several problems with this method of analysis, i.e., Y may be less

    • Sources of financing G’

    • Effects on private investment I’

    • Productivity of government projects

The problems of the simple keynesian multiplier k e70 l.jpgSlide 70

The Problems of the Simple Keynesian Multiplier k E

  • Sources of financing G’

  • Increasing Tax

    • will exert a contractionary effect on the economy

  • Increasing Money Supply

    • will generate an inflationary pressure

  • Increasing Debt

    • will increase the demand for loanable fund as well as interest rate  affect private investment

The problems of the simple keynesian multiplier k e71 l.jpgSlide 71

The Problems of the Simple Keynesian Multiplier k E

  • Effects on Private Investment I’

  • Private investment may be crowded out when government increases its expenditure

  • It is questionable that the government can really produce something which is desired by the consumers

  • Besides, government investment projects are usually less productive than private investment projects

The problems of the simple keynesian multiplier k e72 l.jpgSlide 72

The Problems of the Simple Keynesian Multiplier k E

  • Productivity of Government Projects

  • Government projects may not yield a rate of return (MEC / MEI) exceeding the market interest rate.


Copyright © 2014 SlideServe. All rights reserved | Powered By DigitalOfficePro