1 / 18

Properties of Demand Functions

Properties of Demand Functions. Comparative statics analysis of ordinary demand functions -- the study of how ordinary demands x 1 *(p 1 ,p 2 ,m) and x 2 *(p 1 ,p 2 ,m) change as prices p 1 , p 2 and income m change. Own-Price changes:

Download Presentation

Properties of Demand Functions

An Image/Link below is provided (as is) to download presentation Download Policy: Content on the Website is provided to you AS IS for your information and personal use and may not be sold / licensed / shared on other websites without getting consent from its author. Content is provided to you AS IS for your information and personal use only. Download presentation by click this link. While downloading, if for some reason you are not able to download a presentation, the publisher may have deleted the file from their server. During download, if you can't get a presentation, the file might be deleted by the publisher.

E N D

Presentation Transcript


  1. Properties of Demand Functions • Comparative statics analysis of ordinary demand functions -- the study of how ordinary demands x1*(p1,p2,m) and x2*(p1,p2,m) change as prices p1, p2 and income m change. • Own-Price changes: • How does x1*(p1,p2,m) change as p1 changes, holding p2 and m constant?

  2. p1 Own-Price Changes Ordinarydemand curvefor commodity 1 Fixed p2 and m. p1’’’ p1’’ p1’ x1* x1*(p1’) x1*(p1’’’) x1*(p1’’) x1*(p1’’’) x1*(p1’) x1*(p1’’)

  3. Own-Price Changes • The curve containing all the utility-maximizing bundles traced out as p1 changes, with p2 and m constant, is the p1- price offer curve. • The plot of the x1-coordinate of the p1- price offer curve against p1 is the ordinary demand curve for commodity 1.

  4. Own-Price Changes: Cobb-Douglas • Take • Then the ordinary demand functions for commodities 1 and 2 are • What does the demand curve look like? • What does a p1 price-offer curve look like?

  5. p1 Own-Price Changes Ordinarydemand curvefor commodity 1 is Fixed p2 and m. x1* x1*(p1’’’) x1*(p1’) x1*(p1’’)

  6. Own-Price Changes: Perfect complements • Take • Then the ordinary demand functionsfor commodities 1 and 2 are • What does the demand curve look like? • What is the p1 price-offer curve?

  7. p1 Own-Price Changes Ordinarydemand curvefor commodity 1 is Fixed p2 and m. p1’’’ x2 p1’’ m/p2 p1’ x1* x1

  8. Own-Price Changes: Perfect Substitutes • Take • Then the ordinary demand functionsfor commodities 1 and 2 are • What does the demand curve look like? • What is the p1 price-offer curve?

  9. p1 Own-Price Changes Ordinarydemand curvefor commodity 1 Fixed p2 and m. p1’’’ x2 p2 = p1’’ p1 price offer curve p1’ x1* x1

  10. Income Changes • How does the value of x1*(p1,p2,m) change as m changes, holding both p1 and p2 constant? • A plot of quantity demanded against income is called an Engel curve. • A plot of bundles chosen as we vary income is called the income-offer curve. • Draw these two curves for Perfect complements, Cobb-Douglas, and Perfect Substitutes.

  11. Income Changes • In every example so far the income offer curves have all been straight lines for the origin?Q: Is this true in general? • A: No. Income offer curves are straight lines only if the consumer’s preferences are homothetic.

  12. Homotheticity • A consumer’s preferences are homothetic if and only iffor every k > 0. • That is, the consumer’s MRS is the same anywhere on a straight line drawn from the origin. p p Û (x1,x2) (y1,y2) (kx1,kx2) (ky1,ky2)

  13. Why the connection? • Take a budget and choice (x1*,x2*). Double the budget so new budget is 2m. • Notice if (x1,x2) were in the old budget, (2 x1, 2 x2) is in the new budget. • Homotheticity implies that if (x1*,x2*)> (x1,x2) then (2x1*,2x2*)>(2x1,2x2), thus new choice is (2x1*,2x2*). • Notice if you draw a line from origin to (x1*,x2*) it goes through (2x1*,2x2*). • Since these are the choices, the MRS must be the same at both points to be tangent to the ICs.

  14. Homogeneous Utility Functions • U(k x1,k x2)= g(k) u(x1,x2) and g(k)>0. • This implies homotheticity! • U(x1,x2)>U(y1,y2) => g(k) U(x1,x2)> g(k) U(y1,y2) => U(k x1,k x2)>U(k y1,k y2) • Does Cobb-Douglas, Perfect Substitutes, Perfect Complements satisfy this?

  15. Income Effects -- A Nonhomothetic Example • Quasilinear preferences are not homothetic. • For example, • U(1,0)>U(0,3/4) but when k=4, we have U(4,0)<U(0,3)!

  16. Income Effects • A good for which quantity demanded rises with income is called normal. • Therefore a normal good’s Engel curve is positively sloped. • A good for which quantity demanded falls as income increases is called income inferior. • Therefore an income inferior good’s Engel curve is negatively sloped. • A luxury good is where the proportion of income spent on it goes up with income. • The opposite of a luxury good is a necessarygood. • Is a necessary good always inferior? • Is a inferior good always necessary? • Can we have a necessary good w/o a luxury good? Vice-versa? • Can we have an inferior good w/o a luxury good? Vice-versa?

  17. Ordinary and Giffen goods. • A good is called ordinary if the quantity demanded of it always increases as its own price decreases. • If, for some values of its own price, the quantity demanded of a good rises as its own-price increases then the good is called Giffen. • Example of a Giffen good – U(x1,x2)=-e-x1-e-x2

  18. Cross-Price Effects • If an increase in p2 • increases demand for commodity 1 then commodity 1 is a gross substitute for commodity 2. • reduces demand for commodity 1 then commodity 1 is a gross complement for commodity 2. • What happens with Cobb-Douglas preferences?

More Related