1 / 51

Trade Growth and Inequality

Why the Poor Stay Poor. Chapter 3 of the book(circulated). The Persistence of Poverty. What are the transmission properties of income at t to income at t 1?Friedman (1992) regression to the meanIncomes normally distributed and: Positions random Positions fixed. Are All Agents the Same?. Herrnstei

vittorio
Download Presentation

Trade Growth and Inequality

An Image/Link below is provided (as is) to download presentation Download Policy: Content on the Website is provided to you AS IS for your information and personal use and may not be sold / licensed / shared on other websites without getting consent from its author. Content is provided to you AS IS for your information and personal use only. Download presentation by click this link. While downloading, if for some reason you are not able to download a presentation, the publisher may have deleted the file from their server. During download, if you can't get a presentation, the file might be deleted by the publisher.

E N D

Presentation Transcript


    1. Trade Growth and Inequality Professor Christopher Bliss Hilary Term 2004 Fridays 10-11 a.m.

    2. Why the Poor Stay Poor Chapter 3 of the book (circulated)

    3. The Persistence of Poverty What are the transmission properties of income at t to income at t+1? Friedman (1992) regression to the mean Incomes normally distributed and: Positions random Positions fixed

    4. Are All Agents the Same? Herrnstein and Murray (The Bell Curve) Income=F(IQ) They claim that technological change has been such that: F(IQ))/F(100) has been falling over time for values of IQ well below the mean=100

    5. Adam Smith Little else is requisite to carry a state to the highest degree of opulence from the lowest barbarism but peace, easy taxes, and a tolerable administration of justice: all the rest being brought about by the natural course of things. (Lecture 1775)

    6. Karl Marx The country that is more developed industrially only shows to the less developed the image of its own future. (quoted by Myrdal 1968, p. 674)

    7. The Kuznets Model Initially population in low-level equality Growth takes the form of movement to higher level “modern” productivity While some move but not others, inequality increases As all eventually modernize inequality declines

    8. Problems with the Kuznets story The cross-section evidence does not confirm it The idea of low-level equality is also not in accord with the evidence The curve is caused by differential adjustment rates – why does this happen?

    9. The Stiglitz MASS Model Solow-Swan with many agents All supply same labour and save the same proportion of all income

    10. Stiglitz Model Result Let k* satisfy: s.F[k*,1]-g.k*=0 All agents converge to holding k*

    11. Weakening Stiglitz assumptions The quantity of labour supplied by an individual may vary with capital owned by that agent. It must have a positive limit as k goes to zero. The share of saving in total income may vary monotonically with capital owned by the agent. It must have a positive limit as k goes to zero.

    12. Convergence and the Discount Rate Utility and Consumption Discount Rates Distinguished Endogenous Discount Rates Do the poor have high discount rates?

    13. Discount Rates and Dynamic Inconsistency It is not necessary to assume that the poor discount utility at a high rate (see below) Endogenous discount rates give inconsistency (Strotz)

    14. Strotzian Inconsistency

    15. Strotzian Inconsistency cont. With consumption in the range 99 to 100 the discount factor (the weighting of future utility against current) is approximately 0.9 per period. With consumption in the range 20 to 22 it is not less than 0.5 per period. Viewed from time 1 the present value of utility for respectively I, II and III is 133.25, 132.65 and 130.78. In each case these totals are arrived at using weights (1,0.9,0.81).

    16. Strotzian Dynamic Inefficiency cont. Now the discount factor is 0.5, hence the present values of the part sequences I and II are respectively 32.5 and 33.

    17. The Elasticity of Inter-temporal Substitution (EIS) ? =-c(d2U/dc2)/dU/dc If dU/dc = u ? =-c(du/dc)/u

    18. The Optimal Growth Condition -(du/dt)/u = F1[k,1] – d ?(dc/dt)/c = F1[k,1] – d EIS*growth consumption = MPK – U discount rate

    24. The Diamond Capital Model Consumer lives two periods Supplies 1 unit of labour in Period 1 Divides the wage between consumption and saving Aggregate saving is the economy capital stock That capital plus the return is Period 2 consumption

    25. Diamond Model: kt-1 determines kt Max U[ct] + ?U[ct+1] Subject to: ct +(1/1+rt) ct+1 ? kt +wt wt = F2[kt-1,1] 1+rt = F1[kt,1]

    26. Diamond Model The fundamental theorem Theorem kt increases with kt-1 This makes possible multiple equilibria

    28. Diamond Multiplicity and Poverty Traps This idea is not influential: Why not? Seldom realised in connection with two popular model features: ?stability of SS solutions of interest ?simple standard functional forms

    29. Diamond Model: The Corner Steady State Are there zero-capital economies? The Empty Quarter of Saudi Arabia? Any Corner solution can be converted to a positive income SS by allowing production with zero-capital

    30. Diamond Model Multiple Solution I Cobb-Douglas preferences U[ct,ct+1] = ct?.ct+1 ?-1 Where ? > 0.5 gives discounting Then: kt = ?.F2[kt-1,1] In SS: k = ?.F2[k,1] Both sides increase with k. Strict concavity requires F211[k,1] < 0

    31. The Concavity Condition with Cobb-Douglas With Cobb-Douglas F2[k,1] = A(1-a)ka F211[k,1] = -Aa(1-a)2ka-2 < 0 So in the Cobb-Douglas case we have uniqueness

    32. Diamond model and the elasticity of inter-temporal substitution With Cobb-Douglas production and a constant EIS there is a unique non-degenerate steady state With a variable EIS this is no longer the case (see the next figure)

    34. Which Model Diamond or Ramsey? Diamond allows a SS poverty trap, which the one-agent Ramsey model excludes. Diamond is most clearly appropriate for a rich country with large funded pension schemes. In poor countries, however, parents invest for their children, by buying education or land.

    35. Implications for Policy Solow style models do not support the Kuznets view of inequality Non-concave models permit poverty traps Even when all agents converge inequality may not be monotonic Convergence is not a justification for inaction

    36. Ch. 4 Convergence in Practice and Theory Cross-section growth empirics starts with Baumol (1986) He looks at ß-convergence ß-convergence v. s-convergence - Friedman (1992) De Long (1988) – sampling bias

    37. Barro and Sala-i-Martin World-wide comparative growth “Near complete” coverage (Summers-Heston data) minimizes sampling bias Straight test of ß-convergence Dependent variable is growth of per-capita income 1960-85 Correlation coefficient between growth and lnPCI60 for 117 countries is .227

    38. Table 4.1 Simple regression result N=117 F=6.245

    39. Correlation and Causation Correlation is no proof of causation BUT Absence of correlation is no proof of the absence of causation Looking inside growth regressions perfectly illustrates this last point

    40. The spurious correlation A spurious correlation arises purely by chance Assemble 1000 “crazy” ordered data sets That gives nearly half a million pairs of such variables Between one such pair there is bound to be a correlation that by itself will seem to be of overwhelming statistical significance

    41. Most correlations encountered in practice are not “spurious” But they may well not be due to a simple causal connection The variables are each correlated causally with another “missing” variable As when the variables are non-stationary and the missing variable is time

    42. Two examples of correlating non-stationary variables The beginning econometrics student’s consumption function ct = a + ßyt + et But surely consumption is causally connected to income ADt = a + ßTSt + et where TS = teachers’ salaries AD = arrests for drunkeness

    43. Regression analysis and missing variables A missing variable plays a part in the DGP and is correlated with included variables This is never a problem with Classical Regression Analysis Barro would say that the simple regression of LnPCI60 on per capita growth is biassed by the exclusion of extra “conditioning” variables

    44. Table 4,2 Growth and extra variables Sources * Barro and Sala-i-Martin (1985) * Barro-Lee data set

    45. Table 4.3 Regression result N = 73 F = 8.326 R2 = .4308

    46. Table 4.4 Regression with One Conditioning Variable

    47. Looking Inside Growth Regressions I g is economic growth ly is log initial per capita income z is another variable of interest, such as I/Y, which is itself positively correlated with growth. All these variables are measured from their means.

    48. Inside growth regressions II We are interested in a case in which the regression coefficient of g on ly is near zero or positive. So we have: v{gly}=0 where v is the summed products of g and ly

    49. Inside Growth regressions III Thus v{gly} is N times the co-variance between g and ly. Now consider the multiple regression: g=ßly+?z+e (3)

    50. Inside Growth Regressions IV

    51. Inside Growth Regressions V So that: v{glY}=(ß)(v{gg})+(?)(v{gz}) (5) Then if v{glY}=0 and v{gz}>0, (5) requires that either ß or ?, but not both, be negative. If v{glY}>0 then ß and ? may both be positive, but they cannot both be negative. One way of explaining that conclusion is to say that a finding of ß-convergence with an augmented regressions, despite growth and log initial income not being negatively correlated, can happen because the additional variable (or variables on balance) are positively correlated with initial income.

More Related