1 / 38

A Century of Work and Leisure

A Century of Work and Leisure. by Valerie A. Ramey and Neville Francis. Has Leisure Increased Over the Last Century?. Keynes (1930) Economic Possibilities for Our Grandchildren Lebergott (1993), Greenwood & Vandebroucke (2005): leisure has increased dramatically over the last century

verlee
Download Presentation

A Century of Work and Leisure

An Image/Link below is provided (as is) to download presentation Download Policy: Content on the Website is provided to you AS IS for your information and personal use and may not be sold / licensed / shared on other websites without getting consent from its author. Content is provided to you AS IS for your information and personal use only. Download presentation by click this link. While downloading, if for some reason you are not able to download a presentation, the publisher may have deleted the file from their server. During download, if you can't get a presentation, the file might be deleted by the publisher.

E N D

Presentation Transcript


  1. A Century of Work and Leisure by Valerie A. Rameyand Neville Francis

  2. Has Leisure Increased Over the Last Century? • Keynes (1930) Economic Possibilities for Our Grandchildren • Lebergott (1993), Greenwood & Vandebroucke (2005): leisure has increased dramatically over the last century • Prescott (1986) and DGE models No secular trends in leisure

  3. Annual Hours Worked Per Worker in the U.S. (Maddison’s data)

  4. Annual Hours Worked in Business (Divided by Civilian Non-Institutional Population Ages 16+)

  5. New Measures of Leisure Per Capita • New measure of “per capita” Entire population • Comprehensive measure of non-leisure time - Work-for-pay hours - School hours - Home production hours

  6. How Should We Measure “Per Capita?”

  7. Standard Measure of “Per Capita” • Civilian non-institutional population = total non-institutional population ages 16 and over – armed forces. • Justification? Notion of “available workforce”

  8. Why Not Use Total Population? Theoretical Basis: Standard model with explicit population growth Choose consumption ctand leisure ltto maximize: where Nt is total population Empirical Basis: The consumption of children is counted in c. Why don’t we count their leisure in l?

  9. Importance of Accounting for Children Consider a model with perfect substitutability of consumption and leisure of adults and children in household utility. Let c1 = per capita consumption by children, c2 = per capita consumption by adults h1 = per capita hours worked by children, h2 = per capita hours worked by adults θ = fraction of population that is children The representative household maximizes: subject to: and h1, h2, c1, c2  0. If w1 < w2, then it is optimal to set h1 = 0 and Increase in the fraction of children leads to an increase in h2, hours per capita of adults. Thus, adult time use is affected by the presence of dependents with lower productivity.

  10. Population Ages 0-15 as a Fraction of Total Population

  11. Population Ages 65+ as a Fraction of Total Population

  12. Comprehensive Measures ofNon-Leisure Time • Work for pay (including government) • Commuting time • School Hours • Home Production

  13. What is Leisure? Hawrylshyn (1971) distinguishes leisure from household work by defining household work activities as “those economic services produced in the household and outside the market, but which could be produced by a third person hired on the market without changing the utility to members of the household.”

  14. Ratings of Activity Enjoyment – 1985 (From Robinson and Godbey Appendix O)

  15. Accounting for Hours Worked for Pay The standard RBC measure excludes hours worked in government (civilian and military). Is that important for trends?

  16. Government Hours as a Fraction of Total Work Hours

  17. Measuring Total Hours • Includes private hours (establishment, self-employed, unpaid family workers) plus government hours • Use Kendrick data for early period • Use BLS private hours index upweighted by BEA full-time equivalent employment numbers

  18. New Estimates of Annual Market Hours Per Worker

  19. Commuting Time • Time diary estimates from 1965 – 2003 suggest commute times are a relatively constant 10 % of hours worked. • Scant evidence early in the century - Average commute distances for shorter urban workers, farmers - But modes of urban transportation were slower - Hours per worker, days per week • Rodrigue (2004) argues time spent commuting for urban workers was relatively constant over 20th Century • We assume commute time is 10% of hours worked for entire century

  20. Accounting for Hours Spent in School

  21. School Enrollment Rates

  22. Estimating School Hours Annual school hours = (enrollment in grades K – 8 ) ∙ (avg. days attended by enrollee) ∙ 5.5 hours + (enrollment in grades 9 - 12 ) ∙ (avg. days attended by enrollee) ∙ 7 hours + {(enrollment in college) ∙ [(fraction full-time) + 0.3 ∙ (fraction part-time)] ∙ 165 days ∙ 8 hours}

  23. Annual Per Capita Hours Spent on School for Ages 5-22

  24. Hours Spent in School as a Fraction of Total Market Work

  25. Accounting for Hours Spent in Home Production

  26. Conventional Wisdom “The diffusion of household utilities and appliances dramatically reduced the hours spent in household chores.”

  27. Estimating Home Production Hours • We use data from time diaries when possible, since they are considered the most reliable measure of both market work and home production hours • Strategy: • gather time diary estimates by sex-age-employment status cells • interpolate between years for each cell • weight cell by fraction of population in that cell.

  28. Estimates of Hours of Housework per Week by Nonemployed Women Ages 18-64

  29. Are the Early Studies Representative? • Samples were not nationally representative • Urban samples tended to have above average income • But most samples were rural, which had less access to electricity, market goods, etc. • Evidence suggests that poor urban households did not do more housework – “being poor meant being dirty”, relied on “bakery bread.” • Bryant (1996) adjusts for non-representativeness. Our estimates are consistent with his.

  30. Why Didn’t the Diffusion of AppliancesReduce Housework? • Appliances replaced low-wage immigrant labor • Decline in “maiden aunts” % of nonemployed women living in other’s house with no children of own: 18% in 1900, 7.6% in 1960. • Cross-section and time series studies on appliances: more appliances lead to more household production output • Betty Friedan (1963) The Feminine Mystique • Mokyr (2000): Revolution in sanitation, germ theory of disease and nutrition theory increased demand for cleanliness just as appliances were diffusing

  31. Estimates of Housework by Employment & Sex Category (ages 18-64)

  32. Children’s Home Production Estimates from the 1920s are similar to those from the 1980s: Ages 5-14: 3 hours a week Ages 15-17: 5 hours a week

  33. Average Weekly Hours of Housework of Adults

  34. Hours Per Capita in Various Activities

  35. Per Capita Market-Oriented Hours

  36. Measuring Leisure • Time endowment is 24 hours per day, 365 days per year • Most personal care time ranks high on enjoyment index (sleeping, eating), so we do not subtract it from leisure • Personal care time is relatively constant at 75 hours per week

  37. Annual Leisure Hours Per Capita

  38. Conclusions • New measures suggest leisure per capita now is about equal to leisure per capita in 1900 • Our results are different from the standard ones because we track the leisure of the entire population and we don’t count schooling as leisure. • Keynes prediction has not come true yet for the US

More Related