1 / 31

Industrial Organization or Imperfect Competition

Industrial Organization or Imperfect Competition. Univ. Prof. dr. Maarten Janssen University of Vienna Summer semester 2011 Week 3 (March 24 - 25). Price cost. P M. D(p). Q M. MR. Q. 2. Price Discrimination. Incentives for price discrimination. Price cost. Price cost.

Download Presentation

Industrial Organization or Imperfect Competition

An Image/Link below is provided (as is) to download presentation Download Policy: Content on the Website is provided to you AS IS for your information and personal use and may not be sold / licensed / shared on other websites without getting consent from its author. Content is provided to you AS IS for your information and personal use only. Download presentation by click this link. While downloading, if for some reason you are not able to download a presentation, the publisher may have deleted the file from their server. During download, if you can't get a presentation, the file might be deleted by the publisher.

E N D

Presentation Transcript


  1. Industrial Organization or Imperfect Competition Univ. Prof. dr. Maarten Janssen University of Vienna Summer semester 2011 Week 3 (March 24 - 25)

  2. Price cost PM D(p) QM MR Q 2. Price Discrimination • Incentives for price discrimination Price cost Price cost Economic Surplus not appropriated by the seller! PM PM D(p) D(p) M MC QM MR Q Q

  3. Price Discrimination • First Degree (or perfect) • Personalised pricing • Third Degree (group pricing) • Observe a group signal and charge different prices to different groups • Second degree (menu of contracts, versioning) • Offer a menu of price-quantity (quality,…) bundles and let consumers choose

  4. First-Degree or Perfect Price Discrimination • Practice of charging each consumer the maximum amount he or she will pay for each incremental unit • Permits a firm to extract all surplus from consumers

  5. First-degree: optimal pricing rule • P(x) is the inverse demand function • When charging for each additional unit x price P(x) the firm’s profit equals • Optimisation yields P(x) = C’(x) • Which is the definition of the perfectly competitive price • Hence, efficient allocation

  6. Price Fixed Fee = Profits Per Unit Charge 4 MC D Quantity Perfect price discrimination:Two-Part Tariff Implementation 1. Set price at marginal cost. 2. Compute consumer surplus. 3. Charge a fixed-fee equal to consumer surplus.

  7. Two-Part Tariff: optimal pricing rule • Total price for x units T(x) = A + px, where A is fixed fee and p price per unit • When consumer buys x units, net utility equals U(x) – A – px. • Given T(x), consumer buys x* units, where U’(x*) = p • Participation constraint U(x*) – A – px* ≥ 0 • Max A + (p-c)x by choosing A and p given participation constraint and optimal consumer choice • Obviously, in the optimum PC binds and we should have U’(x*) = p = c. Moreover, A = U(x*) –cx*

  8. Caveats with perfect pricediscrimination • Even though it leads to an efficient outcome, is it a fair distribution of wealth in the society? • In practice, transactions costs and information constraints make it difficult to implement (but car dealers and some professionals try to come close). • Arbitrage: Price discrimination won’t work if consumers can resell the good.

  9. Third Degree Price Discrimination • The practice of charging different groups of consumers different prices for the same product • Examples: • Journals, software [institutions, individuals, students] • International pricing • Physicians [rich and poor patients]

  10. Third Degree Price Discrimination • Suppose the total demand for a product is comprised of two groups with different elasticities, 1 < 2 • Notice that group 2 is more price sensitive than group 1 • Profit-maximizing prices? • P1 = [1/(1 - 1/1)]  MC • P2 = [1/(1 - 1/2)]  MC • More price sensitive consumers pay lower prices • Usually, people with lower incomes (students) • Even if firms have no redistribution intention

  11. Price Cost Db(p) Pb P Da(p) Da+Db Pa MC Qa Qb Q Qa Qb Qb Qa Welfare aspects ofThird Degree Price Discrimination - Firms are better off - Low (high) elasticity consumers are worse (better) off

  12. Welfare aspects I – Analysis constant MC • Without discrimination charge Pm, sell ΣiQmi = ΣiDi(Pm). Profit π= (Pm – c) ΣiQmi • With discrimination charge Pi, sell Qi = D(Pi) and π= Σi(Pi - c)Qi • ΔW = Σi {(Pi - c)Qi- (Pm - c)Qmi} + Σi {Si(Pi)- Si(Pm)}, where ΔW change in welfare because of discrimination and Si surplus of group i • Note that δSi/δp = - Di(p) and δ2Si/δp2 = - δ Di(p)/δp > 0 (surplus is convex)

  13. Welfare aspects: Analysis II • Convexity implies that Si(Pi)- Si(Pm) ≥ S’i(Pm){Pi - Pm} = - Qmi{Pi - Pm} • So, ΔW ≥ Σi {(Pi - c)Qi - (Pm - c)Qmi – Qmi(Pi – Pm)} = Σi(Pi - c)(Qi - Qm). • Also, Si(Pm)- Si(Pi) ≥ S’i(Pi){Pm - Pi} • Implying ΔW ≤ (Pm - c){Σi (Qi - Qmi)}. • So, if price discrimination does not result in more output being sold, then welfare declines • No surprise: discrimination leads to marginal rates of substitution being different among different consumers. Generally, inefficient from distributional perspective.

  14. Welfare aspects: Linear Demand Analysis • Qi = ai - biPi • Straightforward calculations for the discrimination case give • Pi = (ai + cbi)/2bi • Qi = (ai - cbi)/2 • Without discrimination (assuming all consumers are served (buy)) • Pm = (Σiai + c Σibi)/2(Σibi ) • Qm = (Σiai - c Σibi)/2 • As Σi (Qi - Qmi) = 0, price discrimination does not lead to welfare improvement (with linear demand), or can it?

  15. Welfare aspects when some markets are not served Price Cost Pb = P Db(p) Pa Da+Db MC Da(p) Qa Qb = Q Qb Qa

  16. Caveats with third degree pricediscrimination • In practice, the seller needs to be able to observe the characteristics of different consumers. • Price discrimination won’t work if consumers can resell the good (arbitrage) or (successfully) pretend to be of a different group • Interesting angle to discuss economic aspects around the issue of privacy (cf., Google – internet): price discrimination can only work if firms have some information about consumers

  17. Second Degree Price Discrimination • The practice of offering a menu of contracts intended to sort out (screen) consumers of different types • For example, by setting a two-part tariff T(x) = A + px, where consumers can choose any quantity they want • Examples: • Insurance companies, airlines, utilities (water, electricity, telephony), etc.

  18. Price Cost P2(Q) P1(Q) MC p*=MC Q Q1 Q2 2nd Degree Price Discrimination at work Linear two part tariff: T=A + pq Charge p* = c Charge fixed fee A = CS1(c) Fixed Fee = CS1(c)

  19. What is the optimal two-part tariff ? Preliminary results • Two groups of consumers, with utility function θiV(x) – T, θ1 <θ2 and λ (1- λ) consumers of group 1 (2) • Consumers demand such that p = θiV’(x). To make demand linear assume 2V(x) = 1-(1-x)2: Di(p) = 1 – p/θi • Si(p) = θiV(Di(p)) – A - pDi(p) = (θi-p)2/2θi – A • Define 1/θ = λ/θ1 + (1- λ)/θ2 – harmonic mean • D(p) = λD1(p) + (1- λ)D2(p) = 1 – p/θ

  20. What is the optimal two-part tariff ? II • Participation constraints θiV(x) – T ≥ 0 • Obviously if it holds for θ1 then also for θ2 • Highest fixed fee compatible with group 1 buying is A = (θ1-p)2/2θ1 • Thus, optimal two-part tariff when everyone buys has this A and a price p that maximizes λ[A + (p-c)D1(p)] + (1-λ)[A + (p-c)D2(p)] = A + (p-c)D(p) • Yields p = c / (2 – θ/θ1) > c • Thus, optimal price per unit is larger than marginal cost! • and smaller than the monopoly price provided all both groups buy at this price, i.e., (c+ θ2)/2 < θ1

  21. Price Cost P2(Q) P1(Q) MC p*=MC Q Q1 Q2 Intuition why c < p Loss on group 1 consumers Gain on group 2 consumers

  22. Math why c < p • Loss on group 1: (p - c)(p/θ1 - c/θ1)/2 = (p-c)2/2θ1 • Gain on group 2: (p - c)(p/θ1 - p/θ2) - (p-c)2/2θ1 • Sum is (p - c)(c/θ1 - p/θ2) • Derivative wrt p is positive for p close to c and θ2 >θ1

  23. Intuition why p < Pm • By reducing p a little bit (starting from Pm) reduction on variable profits (p-c)D(p) is only of second-order – by definition • However, increase in consumer surplus (which can be extracted) is in order of D1(p) (first-order)

  24. Is a linear tariff optimal? T T = A + px θ2V(x) – T θ1V(x) – T x Single crossing property (or sorting condition): When two indifference curves intersect, group 2’s curve is steeper

  25. Incentive Compatibility • It is as if monopolist constructed contract {T1,x1} for group 1 and {T2,x2} for group 2 • Clearly, group 1 does not want to buy contract {T2,x2} and vice versa, i.e., incentive compatible (IC) – contract designed for group I is bought by group I • Viewed in this way, can we design better contracts? • Especially, because none of the IC constraints is binding

  26. T T = A + px θ2V(x) – T θ1V(x) – T x Monopolist can extract more from group 2 without effecting group 1 Monopolist’s indifference curve T – cx is constant

  27. T T = A + px θ2V(x) – T θ1V(x) – T x Optimal contract - graphically T2 Incentive compatibility implies that one cannot make group 2 consumers worse off than this; otherwise they switch to group 1 contract x2

  28. Remarks • How to get this: either just set menu of two contracts, or non-linear set of contracts • In optimal contract: incentive compatibility constraint must be binding • That is why linear contract is not optimal • In optimal contract, indifference curve monopolist and high demand consumer are tangent: group 2’s consumption is socially optimal (x2 = D2(c))

  29. T T = A + px θ2V(x) – T θ1V(x) – T x Non-linear menu- graphically

  30. 2nd Degree Price Discrimination at work; Non-linear two-part tariffs: still better Price Cost Non-Linear two part tariffs: Offer menu {{A1,p1},{A2,p2}} Charge p1 *>c; A1= CS1(p1 *) Charge p2* = c; A2 = A1+B+C+D P2(Q) P1(Q) A1 p1* D B C MC p2* Q Q1 Q2

  31. Conclusion • First degree price discrimination: • Efficient from TS perspective, but extreme distribution of welfare • Third degree price discrimination: • Yields higher profits than single pricing • Ambiguous welfare results vis-à-vis monopoly pricing (depending on whether or not total output increases) • Second degree price discrimination: • Yields higher profits than single pricing • Better for all consumers than single pricing • Two part-tariffs are also better for all

More Related