1 / 24

Truthful Mechanisms for Combinatorial Auctions with Subadditive Bidders

Truthful Mechanisms for Combinatorial Auctions with Subadditive Bidders. Speaker: Shahar Dobzinski Based on joint works with Noam Nisan & Michael Schapira. Combinatorial Auctions. m items, n bidders, each bidder i has a valuation function v i :2 M ->R + . Common assumptions:

tass
Download Presentation

Truthful Mechanisms for Combinatorial Auctions with Subadditive Bidders

An Image/Link below is provided (as is) to download presentation Download Policy: Content on the Website is provided to you AS IS for your information and personal use and may not be sold / licensed / shared on other websites without getting consent from its author. Content is provided to you AS IS for your information and personal use only. Download presentation by click this link. While downloading, if for some reason you are not able to download a presentation, the publisher may have deleted the file from their server. During download, if you can't get a presentation, the file might be deleted by the publisher.

E N D

Presentation Transcript


  1. Truthful Mechanisms for Combinatorial Auctions with Subadditive Bidders Speaker: Shahar Dobzinski Based on joint works with Noam Nisan & Michael Schapira

  2. Combinatorial Auctions • m items, n bidders, each bidder i has a valuation function vi:2M->R+. Common assumptions: • Normalization: vi()=0 • Monotonicity: ST  vi(T) ≥ vi(S) • Goal: find a partition S1,…,Sn such that the total social welfareSvi(Si) is maximized. • Algorithms must run in time polynomial in n and m. • In this talk the valuations are subadditive: for every S,T  M: v(S)+v(T) ≥ v(ST) (but all of our results also hold for submodular valuations)

  3. Truthful Approximations? • A 2 approximation algorithm exists [Feige], and a matching lower bound is also known [Dobzinski-Nisan-Schapira]. • What about truthful approximations? • The private information of each bidder is his valuation.

  4. Outline • A deterministic VCG-based O(m½)-approximation mechanism • An W(m1/6) lower bound on VCG-based mechanisms. • A randomized almost-logarithmic approximation mechanism.

  5. Reminder: Maximal in Range Algorithms • VCG: Allocate Oi to bidder i. Bidder i gets a payment of Sk≠ivk(Ok). • (O1,…,On) is the optimal solution. • Still truthful if we limit the range. • Range := { A=(A1,…,An) |v1,…,vn: A(v1,…,vn)=A } • The Algorithm[Dobzinski-Nisan-Schapira]: • Choose the best allocation where either: • One bidder gets all items OR • Each bidder gets at most one item. • Clearly, the algorithm is maximal-in-range and can be implemented in polynomial time.

  6. Proof of the Approximation Ratio Theorem: If all valuations are subadditive, the algorithm provides an O(m1/2)-approximation. Proof: Let OPT=(L1,..,Ll,S1,...,Sk), where for each Li, |Li|>m1/2, and for each Si, |Si|≤m1/2. |OPT|= Sivi(Li) + Sivi(Si) • Case 2:Sivi(Si) ≥ Sivi(Li) • (“small” bundles contribute most of the optimal social welfare) • Sivi(Si) ≥ |OPT|/2 Claim: Let v be a subadditive valuation and S a bundle. Then there exists an item jS s.t. v({j}) ≥ v(S)/|S|. Proof: immediate from subadditivity. • Thus, for each bidder i that was assigned a small bundle, there is an item ciSi, such that: vi({ci}) > vi(Si) / m1/2. Allocate ci to bidder i. • Case 1: Sivi(Li) > Sivi(Si) • (“large” bundles contribute most of the optimal social welfare) • Sivi(Li) > |OPT|/2 • At most m1/2 bidders get at least m1/2 items in OPT. •  There is a bidder i s.t.: vi(M) ≥ vi(Li) ≥ |OPT|/2m1/2.

  7. Outline • A deterministic VCG-based O(m½)-approximation mechanism • An W(m1/6) lower bound for VCG-based mechanisms. • A randomized almost-logarithmic approximation mechanism.

  8. About the Lower Bound • Why lower bounds on VCG-Based mechanisms (a.k.a. maximal-in-range algorithms)? • Conjectured characterization: All mechanisms that give a good approximation ratio for combinatorial auctions with subadditive bidders are maximal in their range. • Even if the conjecture is false, still the only technique that we currently know.

  9. An W(m1/6) lower bound on VCG-based mechanisms [Dobzinski-Nisan] • We define two complexity: • Cover Number: (approximately) the range size • must be “large” in order to obtain a good approximation ratio. • Intersection Number: a lower bound on the communication complexity. • We therefore want it to be “small” (polynomial) • Lemma (informal): If the cover number is large then the intersection number must be large too. • From now on, only 2 bidders, thus a lower bound of 2.

  10. The Cover Number • Intuitively, the size of the range • But we don’t want to count “degenerate allocations”… • A set of allocations C covers a set of allocations R if for each allocation S in R there is an allocation T in C such that TiCi for i={1,2}. • cover(R) is the size of the smallest set C that covers R. • Observation: An MIR on range C provides a better approximation ratio than on R.

  11. The Cover Number • Lemma: Let A be an MIR algorithm with range R. If cover(R) < em/400, then A provides an approximation ratio of at most 1.99. • Proof: Using the probabilistic method. • Fix an allocation T=(T1,T2) from the minimal cover C. • Construct an instance with additive bidders: v(S) = SjS v({j}) • For each item j, set with probability ½ v1({j})=1 and v2({j})=0 (or vice versa with probability ½ ). • The optimal welfare in this instance is m, but each item j contributes 1 to the welfare provided by T only if we hit the corresponding bundle in T (with probability 1/2). • The expected welfare that T provides is m/2, and we can get a better welfare only with exponential small probability.

  12. The Intersection Number • A set of allocations D is called an intersection set if for each (A1,A2)≠(B1,B2)D we have that A1 intersects B2 and A2 intersects B1. • Let intersect(R) be the size of the largest intersection set in R.

  13. The Intersection Number • Lemma: Let A be an MIR algorithm with range R. Let intersect(R)=d. Then, the communication complexity of A is at least d. • Proof: • Reduction from disjointness: Alice holds a=a1…ad, Bob holds b=b1…bd. Is there some t with at=bt=1? Requires t bits of communication. • Given a disjointness instance, construct a combinatorial auction with subadditive bidders: • Let {(A1,B1),…,(Ad,Bd)} be the intersection set. Set vA(S)=2 if there is an index i s.t. ai=1 and Ai  S. Otherwise vA(S)=1. Similar valuation for Bob. • The valuations are subadditive. • A common 1 bit  optimal welfare of 4. Our algorithm is maximal in range, and the optimal allocation is in the range, so our algorithm always return the optimal solution. But this requires d bits of communication.

  14. Putting it Together • In order to obtain an approximation ratio better than 2, the cover number must be exponentially large. • If the MIR algorithm runs in polynomial time then the intersection number must be polynomial too. • Lemma (informal): If the cover number is exponentially large then the intersection number is exponentially large too. • Corollary: No polynomial time VCG-based algorithm provides an approximation ratio better than 2.

  15. Summary • A deterministic VCG-based O(m½)-approximation mechanism • An W(m1/6) lower bound on VCG-based mechanisms. • A randomized almost-logarithmic approximation mechanism.

  16. Open Questions • Deterministic mechanisms\lower bounds for combinatorial auctions with general valuations? • Is the gap between randomized and deterministic mechanisms essential?

  17. Randomness and Mechanism Design • Randomization might help in mechanism design settings. • Two notions of randomization: • “The universal sense”: a distribution over deterministic mechanisms (stronger) • “In expectation”: truthful behavior maximizes the expectation of the profit (weaker) • Risk-averse bidders might benefit from untruthful behavior. • The outcomes of the random coins must be kept secret.

  18. Results • Feige shows a randomized O(logm/loglogm)-truthful in expectation mechanism. • We show that there exists an O(logm*loglogm) truthful in the universal sense mechanism.

  19. The Framework • Two cases: • Case 1: There is a dominant bidder. • A bidder with v(M) > OPT/(100log m loglog m) (denote the denominator by c) • We can simply allocate all items to this bidder. • Case 2: There is no dominant bidder. • In this case we can use random sampling: partition the bidders into two sets, acquire statistics from one set, and use it to get an approximate solution with the other set. • How to put the two cases together? • Flipping a coin works, but with probability of only ½. • Next we will see how to increase the probability of success to 1-e.

  20. The Mechanism A second price auction with a reserve price of OPT/c I have an estimate of OPT SECPRICE group • Partition the bidders into 3 sets: • STAT with probability e/2, SECPRICE with probability 1-e, and FIXED with probability e/2. • First case: there is a dominant bidder. Statistics Group

  21. The Mechanism • Second case: there is no dominant bidder. A second price auction with a reserve price of OPT/c FIXED group I have a (good) estimate of OPT Statistics Group

  22. Case 2: No “Dominant” Bidder • Assumption: For all bidders vi(OPTi) < OPT / c • In the FIXED group: a fixed-price auction where each item has a price of p (depends on the statistics group) Everything costs p Take your most profitable bundle My price is 2*p Too Expensive! I paid p

  23. Still Missing… • Why does the fixed price auction (with a “good price”) provides a good approximation ratio? • Can we find this “good price” using the statistics group?

  24. A Combinatorial Property of Subadditive Valuations • Lemma: Let v be a subadditive valuation and S a bundle of items. Then we can assign each item in S a price in {0,p} such that: • For each TS: v(T) > SjT|T|*p • |S|*p > v(S)/(100*logm)

More Related