1 / 42

Adverse Selection

Prerequisites. Almost essential Risk Risk-taking. Adverse Selection. MICROECONOMICS Principles and Analysis Frank Cowell. May 2004 . The adverse selection problem. A key aspect of hidden information Information relates to personal characteristics .

sandra_john
Download Presentation

Adverse Selection

An Image/Link below is provided (as is) to download presentation Download Policy: Content on the Website is provided to you AS IS for your information and personal use and may not be sold / licensed / shared on other websites without getting consent from its author. Content is provided to you AS IS for your information and personal use only. Download presentation by click this link. While downloading, if for some reason you are not able to download a presentation, the publisher may have deleted the file from their server. During download, if you can't get a presentation, the file might be deleted by the publisher.

E N D

Presentation Transcript


  1. Prerequisites Almost essential Risk Risk-taking Adverse Selection MICROECONOMICS Principles and Analysis Frank Cowell May 2004

  2. The adverse selection problem • A key aspect of hidden information • Information relates to personal characteristics. • Hidden information about actions is dealt with under “moral hazard.” • Focus on the heterogeneity of agents on one side of the market. • Elementary model of a single seller with multiple buyers Jump to “Moral Hazard”

  3. Overview... Adverse selection Principles Background and outline Monopoly problem Insurance

  4. Key concepts (1) • Contract: • An agreement to provide specified good or service… • …in exchange for specified payment • Type of contract will depend on information available. • Fee schedule: • Set-up involving a menu of contracts • One party draws up the menu. • Allows some selection by other party • Again the type of fee schedule will depend on information available • Types: • Assume that hidden information is well structured • General shape of (e.g.) agents’ preferences is common knowledge • But there is heterogeneity as to (e.g.) intensity of preference • Correspond to different types of agents

  5. Key concepts (2) • Adverse selection: • individuals faced with a contract… • …can choose to accept or reject . • Multiple contracts aimed at different types? • Then some individuals may choose the “wrong” one. • Screening: • Knowing this, other side of market seeks to respond. • Draw up contracts so that the various groups self-select the “right” ones. • “Adverse selection” and “Screening” are effectively equivalent labels. • Based on concept of Bayesian Nash equilibrium • Follow through a simplified version of the game

  6. Screening: extensive-form game • "Nature" chooses a person's type • Probabilities are common knowledge • Firm may offer a contract, not knowing the type 0 p 1-p • Consumer chooses whether to accept contract [LOW] [HIGH] f f [OFFER] [OFFER] [NO] [NO] a b [reject] [accept] [reject] [accept]

  7. Outline of the approach • Begin with monopolist serving a market • heterogeneous customers • differ in terms of taste for the product • other differences (income?) are unimportant • Easy to see what is going on • Main points can be established from case of just two customer types • Lessons from this are easily transferred to other contexts. • Examine these later

  8. Overview... Adverse selection Principles A fee schedule to maximise profits from consumers with known tastes Monopoly problem • Exploitation: full information • Effect of hidden information • "Second-best" solution Insurance

  9. Model structure • Monopoly produces good 1 using good 2 as input. • Constant marginal cost • Zero fixed cost • Good 1 cannot be resold. • The monopoly sells to heterogeneous customers • The firm wants to set up a system of payment. • A fee schedule • Some customer information might be concealed. • Imagine this information in the form of a parameter • Knowledge of each customer's parameter value would help the firm exploit the customer. Some fee schedules

  10. Alternative fee schedules • A straight unit price • Two-part tariff 2 • Multi-part tariff Fee Revenue 3 • 1. F(x1) = px1 1 • 2. F(x1) = F0 + px1 x1 • 3. F(x1) = F0 + p′ x1, x1 ≤ x1 x1 = F0 + p′x1+ p′′ [x1x1], x1 > x1

  11. Single customer type • Suppose there is just one type of customer • Income is y. • Utility is given by • U(x1, x2) = x2 + y(x1) where y(0) = 0. • Zero income effect for good 1 • Welfare can be measured by consumer surplus • Reservation utility level is u = U(y, 0) = y • Firm maximises profits subject to reservation constraint. • Monopoly position means firm can appropriate the surplus. • Can do this by imposing two-part tariff: • Fixed charge F0 . • Price p = c.

  12. A two-part tariff F(x1) p x1 F0

  13. * x1 Exploitative contract • Income • Preferences x2 • Reservation utility • Budget set arising from exploitative contract • Fixed charge • Optimal consumption y  F0 • By not participating consumer can get utility levelu=U(0,y) • Reservation indifference curve is given byU(x1,x2) = u u x1

  14. Heterogeneous consumers • Two groups: a-types and b-types • Groups differ in their incomes and in their tastes. • Each group is internally homogeneous • Introduce the single-crossing condition: • imposes regularity on indifference curves; • makes it possible to compare the groups • easy to introduce “tailor-made” fee schedules

  15. h x2 h x1 Two sets of preferences • a-type indifference curves • b-type indifference curves • Ua(x1a,x2a) = x2a + ta y(x1a) h=a • Ub(x1b,x2b) = x2b + tb y(x1b) • Single-crossing condition is satisfied h=b

  16. Full-information contracts • Assume that there is full information about both types of consumer. • The firm knows • The preferences of both Alf and Bill • The incomes of both Alf and Bill • Therefore • Uses this information to design two-part tariffs... • Tailor-made for each type of consumer. • Forces each down to the reservation utility levels ua and ub • Outcome can be illustrated as follows.

  17. b b x2 x1 a x2 b F0 *b *a x1 x1 a F0 a x1 Exploitation of two groups • Income of Alf and Bill • Preferences of Alf and Bill • Budget sets arising from exploitative contracts yb Alf Bill • Fixed charges  • Optimal consumptions ya  ua ub

  18. Overview... Adverse selection Principles Key issues of the adverse-selection problem Monopoly problem • Exploitation: full information • Effect of hidden information • "Second-best" solution Insurance

  19. Concealed information • Now suppose personal information is private • Can’t observe a customer’s taste characteristic • Can’t implement a fee-schedule conditioned on taste • Possibility of severe loss of profit to the firm. • The reason is that some individuals may masquerade: • High-valuation consumers can claim the contract appropriate to low-valuation consumers • Imitate the behaviour of low-valuation consumers • Enjoy a surplus by “hiding” amongst the others • Will this lead to an inefficient outcome?

  20. b b x2 x1 b F0 *a *b x1 x1 a F0 b F00 Bill’s incentive to masquerade • Bill’s income and preferences • Contract intended for b-type • Contract intended for a-type • Bill would be better off with an a-type contract yb  • Now try cutting the fixed charge on a b-contract • To masquerade as an a-type Bill mimics Alf’s consumption • Bill finds the new b-contract at least as good as an a-contract

  21. Insight from the masquerade • A “pooling contract” is not optimal • By cutting F0 for b-types sufficiently: • the b-types are at least as well off as if they had masqueraded as a-types • the firm makes higher profits • there is allocative efficiency • But this new situation is not a solution: • shows that masquerading is suboptimal • illustrates how to introduce incentive-compatibility • but we have not examined profit maximisation. • Requires separate modelling

  22. Overview... Adverse selection Principles First look at a design problem Monopoly problem • Exploitation: full information • Effect of hidden information • "Second-best" solution Insurance

  23. More on masquerading • Now consider profit maximisation • Build in informational constraints • Will act as additional side constraint on the optimisation problem • Because of this usually called a “second-best” approach • Another way of seeing that a pooling contracts not optimal • Let us examine the elements of an approach.

  24. Elements of the approach • Choose F(•) to maximise profits • Subject to • Participation constraint • Incentive-compatibility constraint • The participation constraint is just as before • Can opt out and not consume at all • Incentive compatibility encapsulates the information problem • Individuals know that tastes cannot be observed • So they can select a contract “meant for” someone else • They will do so if it results in a utility gain • Run through logic of solution...

  25. Logic of the solution: (1) • In principle we have a profit-maximisation problem subject to four constraints: • Low valuation a-types’ participation constraint • High valuation b-types’ participation constraint • a-types' incentive compatibility: must get as much utility as they would from a b-type contract. • b-types' incentive compatibility: must get as much utility as they would from an a-type contract. • But a-types have no incentive to masquerade • They would lose from a b-type contract • So a-type incentive-compatibility constraint is redundant • Can show this formally • Also b-types cannot be forced on to reservation utility level ub. • We’ve seen what happens: they would grab an a-type contract • So b-types’ participation constraint is redundant • So the problem can be simplified….

  26. Logic of the solution: (2) • In practice we have a profit-maximisation problem subject to two constraints: • a-types’ participation constraint • b-types’ incentive compatibility: must get as much utility as they would from an a-type contract. • a-types can be kept on reservation utility level ua • There is an infinity of fee schedules that will do this. • b-types must be prevented from masquerading. • Do this by distorting upwards the unit price for the a-types • Force the b-types down to the indifference curve they could attain with an a-type contract. • Maximise profit from them by charging price=MC. • Check this in a diagram...

  27. b b x2 x1 a x2 a a b x1 x1 x1 a x1 Second-best contracts • Income and preferences • Budget sets for full-information case • The a-type contract • b's utility with an a-type contract yb Alf Bill  • The b-type contract ya  ua

  28. b a x1 x1 h x2 h x1 Second-best contracts (2) • Income and preferences for the two types • The a-type contract • b's utility with an a-type contract • The b-type contract yb  • The attainable set constructed by the firm • Implementing the contract with a multipart tariff. ya  • An a-type is forced down on to the reservation indifference curve. • A b-type gets the utility possible by masquerading as an a-type. ua • Multipart tariff has kink at x1. x1

  29. a b x1 x1 x1 Second-best contracts (3) • Multipart tariff: firm’s viewpoint • An a-type choice • A b-type choice F(x1) • The cost function C(x1) • Profit on each a-type • Profit on each b-type F(•) C(•) Pb Pa x1

  30. Second best: principles • b-types have to be made as well off as they could get by masquerading • So they have to keep some surplus • Full surplus can be extracted from a-types • High valuation b-type contract involves price = MC • "No Distortion at the Top" • Low-valuation a-types face higher price, lower fixed charge than under full information • they consume less than under full information • This acts to dissuade b-types.

  31. Overview... Adverse selection Principles Heterogeneous risk types in an insurance market Monopoly problem Insurance

  32. Adverse selection: competition • So far we have assumed an extreme form of market organisation • Power in the hands of a monopolist • Can draw up menu of contracts • Limited only by possibility of non-participation or masquerading • Suppose the monopoly can be broken • Free entry into the market • Numbers determined by zero-profit condition • What type of equilibrium will emerge? • Will there be an equilibrium? An important case

  33. The insurance problem Jump to “Risk taking” • Apply the standard model of risk-taking. • The individual enjoys a random endowment • Has given wealth y • But faces a potential loss L. • Consider this as a prospectP0 with payoffs (y, y- L) • Individual’s preferences satisfy von-Neumann-Morgenstern axioms • Can use concept of expected utility • If p is probability of loss… • …lope of indifference curve where it crosses the 45º line is –[1–p]/p. • Competitive market means actuarially fair insurance • Slope of budget line given by –[1–p]/p... Graphical representation

  34. _ _ ya ya A single risk type xBLUE • a-type indifference map • income and possible loss • actuarially expected income • actuarially fair insurance with premiumk. • a-type attainable set • • Slope is same on 45 line. • Gets “flatter” as p increases L-k 1- pa -  pa. A • Endowment point P0 has coordinates (y, y –L) P0 • y – L • Full insurance guarantees expected income k xRED 0 y

  35. The insurance problem: types • An information problem can arise if there is heterogeneity of the insured persons. • Assume that heterogeneity concerns probability of loss • a-types: low risk, low demand for insurance • b-types: high risk, high demand for insurance • Types associated with risk rather than pure preference • Each individual is endowed with the prospect P0 . • Begin with full-information case

  36. Efficient risk allocation xBLUE • Endowment point • a-type indifference curves • b-type indifference curves • Attainable set and equilibrium, a-types • Attainable set and equilibrium, b-types • P*a • pb > pa • • A b-type would prefer to get an a-type contract if it were possible P*b 1- pa -  pa. 1- pb -  pb. P0 • y – L xRED 0 y

  37. Possibility of adverse selection • Indifference curves xBLUE • Endowment • a-type (low-risk) insurance contract • • b-type (high-risk) insurance contract • If Bill insures fully with an a-type contract • • If over-insurance were possible... • • (y, y- L) xRED 0

  38. Pooling • Suppose the firm “pools” all customers • Same price offered for insurance to all. • Assume that a-types and b-types are in the proportions (g,1-g) • Pooled probability of loss is therefore • `p := gpa + [1-g] pb • pa <`p< pb • Can this be an equilibrium?

  39. Pooling equilibrium? • Endowment &indiff curves xBLUE • Pure a-type, b-type contracts • Pooling contract, lowg. • Pooling contract, highg. • Pooling contract, intermediateg. • a-type’s choice with pooling • b-type’s unrestricted choice • b-type mimics an a-type • • A profitable contract preferred by a-types but not by b-types `P • • • A proposed pooling contract is always dominated by a separating contract • P0 xRED 0

  40. Separating equilibrium? • Endowment &indiff curves xBLUE • Pure a-type, b-type contracts • b-type would like a pure a-type contract • Restrict a-types in their coverage • Then b-types take efficient contract • a-type’s and b-type’s preferred prospects to (Pa ,P*b) • ~ ^ • A pooled contract preferred by both a-types and b-type P • • P*b ~ Pa • Proposed separating contract might be dominated by a pooling contract. • This could happen if g were large enough • • P0 xRED 0

  41. Insurance model: assessment • Why is the insurance case specially difficult? • Note the special role of parameters pa, pb. • As "type indicators" – shift the indifference curves. • As weights in the evaluation of profits. • The population composition affects profitability • Directly: expected profit on each contract written • Indirectly: through the masquerading process • As before, no pooling equilibrium • But may not be a separating equilibrium

  42. What next? • Consider other fundamental models of information • Signalling models • also hidden personal characteristics... • ...but where the informed party moves first. • Moral hazard • hidden information about individual actions

More Related