1 / 27

Human Capital

Human Capital. In economics we talk about the 4 basic resource groups Land, Labor, Capital (things made to make other things), and Entrepreneurship.

peri
Download Presentation

Human Capital

An Image/Link below is provided (as is) to download presentation Download Policy: Content on the Website is provided to you AS IS for your information and personal use and may not be sold / licensed / shared on other websites without getting consent from its author. Content is provided to you AS IS for your information and personal use only. Download presentation by click this link. While downloading, if for some reason you are not able to download a presentation, the publisher may have deleted the file from their server. During download, if you can't get a presentation, the file might be deleted by the publisher.

E N D

Presentation Transcript


  1. Human Capital

  2. In economics we talk about the 4 basic resource groups Land, Labor, Capital (things made to make other things), and Entrepreneurship. Note labor and entrepreneurship deal with people. Human capital relates to the skills and talents people have developed over time. Here we want to explore the economic theory that people may decide to “invest” in human capital. Examples of this type of investment are formal education (college) and on-the-job training.

  3. Investment in college Here we will work with a graph that lists years of experience on the horizontal axis and earnings on the vertical axis. The earnings are $ benefits net of costs of various options, or choices, over time. Example: person finishes high school and is thinking about college, Choice 1: enter job market right after high school – no out of pocket costs and earnings begin. Choice 2: go to a 4 year school. We assume years of college mean no earnings. Direct cost is tuition and books and the like. Indirect cost is forgone income could have made if working in that “high school” job. After 4 years job is obtained.

  4. $ The graph is called the experience (or age) earnings profile graph. Note earnings rise over most of the time. High school Experience – 0 means right at high school graduation 0

  5. $ Note that if we put a rectangle in each year the rectangle represents the earnings that year. The earnings are really more than the area under the curve, but we focus on that to make the graph easier to work with. Experience – 0 means right at high school graduation 0 4

  6. $ College 4 years Additional earnings of college High school Indirect costs Experience – 0 means right at high school graduation 0 Direct costs 4

  7. The college decision, in a sense, has a plus and a minus in relation to just a high school diploma. The plus side, as seen in the graph, is the additional income one would earn over the lifetime after college. In this graph I have assumed additional earnings is positive and a certain amount. This is different, potentially, for each person. On the minus side we have two major ideas. 1) When in college the individual can not earn the high school income, so we have an opportunity cost of college as the forgone income. This is labeled the indirect cost of college. 2) The direct cost of college is the tuition and books and the like. If the additional earnings of college are greater than the costs of going to college (IN PRESENT VALUE TERMS), then the individual will choose college. Otherwise, the college decision will not pan out.

  8. Changes over time The model seems as though we could go without the graph. We probably could, but it is a shorthand way of remembering the details. Plus the visual in the graph helps us think about changes in the environment. For example, say the earnings to the college degree increase, given all other factors the same. Then the benefit side grows and we would expect more folks to have college pay off. As another example, it seems the college experience is moving to a five year endeavor. Given all else this makes the cost area bigger and thus the more likely college will not pay off.

  9. Job, or work experience, interruptions: When it is expected that a person will have periods of time of no job, then there will be no earnings. It may be the case that during a job interruption that some skills may be lost – the old use it or lose it idea. Thus, the earning profile is interrupted and may shift down due to an absence from work for a period of time. Let’s see this in the graph on the next screen.

  10. After the work interruption we have the earnings profile shift down. Later benefits are lower then. $ Benefits of college College 4 years High school Indirect costs Experience – 0 means right at high school graduation 0 Direct costs 4 Job interruptus

  11. Folks who expect job interruptions in their work life will see the benefits of college shrink, and thus college may no longer be a “profitable” investment. In the US, women have traditionally been the ones with a career of starts and stops in the work world. This model helps us understand why women have been less of the population of colleges and universities in the past. Now, in more modern times we see that the culture of the US has changed such that women are experiencing fewer work interruptions and thus the college decision pays off. We see greater percentages of women in college today.

  12. Human Capital 2

  13. Example based on last section: Assume for a person there is just two years after high school. The individual could work in both years or go to school in the first year and work in the second. Say the individual works both years after high school and earns 20,000 each year. Then the present value is 20,000 + [20,000/(1+r)] (assuming a beginning of year convention and r = .05) = 39,048 If the individual goes to school the first year the cost is 5,000 but income the second year is then 47,000 for a present value = -5,000 +[47,000/(1+r)] = 39,762.

  14. Since the present value for the school series is higher the person would choose school. Another way to see this is the way I mentioned at the end of the previous section - basically the differential cost in the first year has to be outweighed by the addition earning to make college pay off. Here we have -5,000 - 20,000 + [(47,000-20,000)/(1+r)] = 714.29 So, the year of schooling generates enough additional earnings in the second year to overcome the cost of school and forgone income in the first year. Now, in this example the interest rate was assumed to be 5%. But if the interest rate was 15% the year in school would not pay off. (please check the calculation)

  15. The value of r is really determined in the market. Let’s call it the bank rate of interest you would earn if you put your money into a bank in some form (CD’s or something). Now, in reality each of us can choose between many different years of schooling. We next turn to a graph and analysis where years of schooling and yearly income are studied. On the next slide you will see the wage-schooling locus – a line showing the salary that employers are willing to pay a particular worker for every level of schooling. Note 12 on years of schooling is a high school diploma.

  16. $ 25000 23000 20000 Years of schooling 12 13 14

  17. Note three ideas in the graph on the previous slide: 1) The curve is upward sloping – more schooling translates into more yearly income. 2) The slope of the curve is change in income/change in school. If we take the change in school one year at a time then the slope is the change in income. For example, from 12 to 13 years of school we have (23000 – 20000)/(13-12) = 3000, and From 13 to 14 years of schooling we have (25000 – 23000)/(14 – 13) = 2000.

  18. Note 3 – the curve is concave reflecting the fact that more schooling yields more income, but the additional income each year is less and less – the proverbial diminishing returns. From the three points in the graph I will put the values in a table and add some details. Year Income slope MRR 12 20000 xxx xxx 13 23000 3000 3000/20000 = .15 or 15% 14 25000 2000 2000/23000 = .087 or 8.7% So, the slope can be used to calculate the MRR, the marginal rate of return to schooling.

  19. Notice that when the person considers the 13th year of school they will give up making 20000 after the 12th year in the anticipation of making 23000 after the 13th year. The additional 3000 on the 13th year is the return on the 20000 given up, for a marginal rate of return of 15%. Since there are diminishing returns to school the marginal rate of return will be a curve that slopes downward from left to right, as seen on the next screen. I have included the values from our running example.

  20. Rates 15% 8.7% MRR Years of Schooling 13 14

  21. Decision rule on how much school to take: Add years of schooling as long as the MRR is greater than rate you can earn on funds in the bank (or other investment vehicles), stop adding when the MRR = bank rate and never add years when MRR < bank rate. On the next graph you see the general MRR graph with a bank rate added in horizontally. The amount of schooling to take is s*. The reason you would not take more than s* is that if you did you would give up money from working to be in school. But since the bank rate is higher than the MRR on that year of schooling if you work and put the money in the bank then you can have more than what you would have earned after the additional year of school. Plus you wouldn’t stop short of s* because schooling has the best return you can make at that point.

  22. Rates Bank rate MRR Years of Schooling S*

  23. Differences in “bank rates” Say you have two people who face the same wage schooling locus, and thus the same MRR curve. If they have different “bank rates” (really rates of return in other areas), then they will not take the same amount of schooling. The person who has lower alternatives elsewhere will take more schooling. With this scenario in mind, we have been talking theory but practice, or reality, can be used. If people only differ in their rates of return in other areas, then the person with more schooling and higher income can be compared with the person with less schooling and less income and we can observe different points of the wage schooling locus. We get the extra income earned by the extra schooling.

  24. But what if people have the same “bank rates” and differ in their abilities – in other words people have different wage schooling loci and hence different MRR’s to schooling? If person A gets more out of schooling than person B, then A’s wage schooling locus sort of rotates counterclockwise around the bottom left point on the locus (and is thus steeper and higher at every year of schooling) and the MRR curve would be farther to the right. Let’s see these graphs on the next screen. Person B takes less schooling and gets a lower wage.

  25. $ rates Person A Person A Person B Person B Years of schooling Years of schooling

  26. Conundrum When we observe different people having different years of schooling and different wages, we might want to fall into a line of thinking that says, well if we just get the lower wage earner more schooling they would have higher wages. They probably would, but not as much higher as we expect. Think back to person A and person B. In the real world we observe person A make more and have more schooling. What we may not observe is the differences in what each gets out of school. If we think person B, if encouraged to get as much schooling as person A, will have the same income as A after the additional schooling, we are wrong. Person B does not get as much out of schooling as person A. Person B will end up short of the income of person A

  27. Public policy problem If there really is an ability bias in the data of the real world (meaning that the difference in earning comes from not only differences in schooling but also difference in what one gets out of school), then spending tax dollars to encourage more schooling 1. May leave some disillusioned because they won’t get as much as they had hoped, 2. May cost more than the benefits received – the encouragement will likely cost dollars and may be justified in that it will generate more income taxes. But the more income taxes may be overestimated.

More Related