1 / 57

Executive Compensation in Widely-Held US Firms

Executive Compensation in Widely-Held US Firms. ESNIE 2007 Jesse Fried Boalt Hall School of Law U.C. Berkeley. Overview of Presentation. Why study U.S. CEO pay? 2 conflicting views classical “optimal contracting” “managerial power” approach Managerial power approach: in depth

mihaly
Download Presentation

Executive Compensation in Widely-Held US Firms

An Image/Link below is provided (as is) to download presentation Download Policy: Content on the Website is provided to you AS IS for your information and personal use and may not be sold / licensed / shared on other websites without getting consent from its author. Content is provided to you AS IS for your information and personal use only. Download presentation by click this link. While downloading, if for some reason you are not able to download a presentation, the publisher may have deleted the file from their server. During download, if you can't get a presentation, the file might be deleted by the publisher.

E N D

Presentation Transcript


  1. Executive Compensation in Widely-Held US Firms ESNIE 2007 Jesse Fried Boalt Hall School of Law U.C. Berkeley

  2. Overview of Presentation • Why study U.S. CEO pay? • 2 conflicting views • classical “optimal contracting” • “managerial power” approach • Managerial power approach: in depth • Sources of power • “Outrage Constraint” & “Camouflage” • Costs to shareholders • Policy implications

  3. A picture is worth 1000 words

  4. Why study U.S. CEO pay? • Economic importance • Amounts • Incentive effects • Managerial effort • Decision-making • Window into functioning of U.S. corporate governance system generally • Theoretical interest • Setting for testing agency/governance/labor market theories • Good data (public firms) • Interaction among economics/social norms /political & legal institutions • Public fascination

  5. Two views of CEO pay • Optimal contracting approach • E.g., Murphy (1999); Core, Guay & Larcker (2001); Gabaix & Landier (2007); Kaplan (2007) • Managerial power approach • E.g. Bebchuk & Fried (2002,03,04,05); Yermack (1997); Bertrand & Mullainathan (2001); Blanchard & Lopez-de-Silanes & Shleifer (1994)

  6. Shared premise of both views • Managerial agency problem • Managers of widely-held public firms have significant power • Berle & Means (1932) • Jensen & Meckling (1976): “agency problem” • Managers use power to benefit selves • Empire building (Jensen, 1974; Williamson, 1964) • Failure to distribute excess cash (Jensen, 1986) • Entrenchment (Shleifer & Vishny, 1989)

  7. Optimal K Approach • Classical financial economic view • Executive pay is remedy to agency problem • Boards design pay scheme to • Compensate and retain executives • Incentivize managers to increase shareholder value • Main flaw: due to political limitations on pay amounts, CEOs pay may be insufficiently high powered • Jensen & Murphy, 1990; Kaplan 2006

  8. Managerial Power Approach • Executive compensation is potential remedy to managerial agency problem • But it is also part of the agency problem itself • Managers use their positional power to get pay • excessive • too decoupled from own performance • weakens incentives to generate shareholder value • perverts incentives • Arrangements deviate from optimal K

  9. Managerial power approach • Sources of Managerial Power • “Outrage constraint” • “Camouflage” • Pay Distortions • Going forward: what should be done

  10. Sources of Managerial Power (1) • Optimal K assumes arm’s length bargaining • b/w board & CEO • But why? • if they assume executives not “hard-wired” to serve shareholders, why should they presume directors will automatically seek to do so?

  11. Sources of Managerial Power (2) • CEOs have power over directors • Economic Incentives • directorship: $200K, perks, prestige, connections • Until now, CEOs control renomination to board • Social factors • Collegiality • Loyalty • Cognitive dissonance (directors are current/former executives) • Personal costs of favoring executives are small

  12. Result of Managerial Power • Managers want pay that is • Higher • More decoupled from performance (easier to get) • Boards routinely approve executive pay deals that do not serve shareholders • Pay likely too high • Pay decoupled from performance • Dilutes incentives • Distort incentives

  13. Only a slight exaggeration…

  14. Evidence of power-pay effects • CEO pay higher, less performance-based when • board weaker • Larger board, more “independent” directors appt’d by CEO, directors serving on multiple boards, CEO is board chair (Core, Holthausen & Larcker, 1999) • no large outside shareholder • eg Lambert, Leicker, Weigelt 1993 • fewer “pressure-resistant” institutional shareholders • David, Kochar, Levitas 1998 • more anti-takeover provisions • Borokhovich, Brunarski, Parrino 1997

  15. Constraints on Managerial Power? (1) • Corporate law? • State corporate law defers to board compensation decisions under “business judgment rule” (e.g. Disney) • Takeover market discipline? • Staggered boards • Courts allow “poison pills” • Hostile takeovers expensive, rare

  16. Constraints on Power? (2) • Election of new directors? • Corporation sends out proxy materials with names of board nominees • Check “yes” or “withhold” • Send proxy back to company to be voted “yes” or “withhold” • Unless competing proxy, 1 “yes” vote gets director elected under “plurality voting rule” • Don’t need approval of majority of votes, just plurality • No competing proxies • Costs of mailing competing proxy high • Managers won’t release shareholder list • Collective action problem • Result: 99% elections uncontested

  17. “Outrage Constraint” • Outrage Constraint • Boards’ main constraint: adverse publicity and “outrage” • Outrage imposes social and economic costs • embarrassment • shareholders more likely to support (rare) challenge to management • Evidence of publicity’s effect • Thomas & Martin (1999) • Dyck & Zingales (2004) • Wu (2004)

  18. “Camouflage” • Fear of outrage leads firms to “camouflage” pay • Pay designers try to obscure and legitimize • amount of pay • performance-insensitivity

  19. Camouflage pre-1992: • An SEC official describes the pre-1992 state of affairs as follows: “The information [in the executive compensation section] was wholly unintelligible . . . . Depending on the company’s attitude toward disclosure, you might get reference to a $3,500,081 pay package spelled out rather than in numbers. ………. Someone once gave a series of institutional investor analysts a proxy statement and asked them to compute the compensation received by the executives covered in the proxy statement. No two analysts came up with the same number. The numbers that were calculated varied widely.”[1] • [1].Linda C. Quinn, Executive Compensation under the New SEC Disclosure Requirements, 63 U. Cin. L. Rev. 769, 770-71 (1995).

  20. 1992: Summary Pay Table (SEC) • Firms required to clearly report most forms of compensation in tables with dollar amounts • Salary • Bonus • Stock options (number) • Long-term incentive compensation • Comp table became focus of • Media, economists, shareholders

  21. Post 1992 Camouflage • Pay designers began relying heavily on • forms of compensation not reportable in any column in comp table • post-exit payments (e.g. pensions, golden parachutes) • low-interest loans (Worldcom: $400 million) • performance-insensitive compensation that can be reported as something other than “salary” • E.g.: “guaranteed bonus”

  22. Other CEO pay distortions (1) • Non-equity pay • weakly linked to performance • often driven by luck (e.g. oil company earnings) • bonuses • have low “goalposts” • often tied to manipulable metrics (accounting earnings)

  23. Other CEO pay distortions (2) • Equity pay • Option plans fail to filter out windfalls • Most stock price increases do not reflect • Firm-specific factor • CEO’s contribution • Firms could use market/sector-based indexing but don’t • Backdating accentuates windfalls • Few restrictions on unwinding • Managers not required to hold shares (diluting incentives) • Can sell on inside information (perverting incentives)

  24. Costs to shareholders • Direct • Top-5 pay = 10% of aggregate corporate earnings during 2001-2003 Bebchuk & Grinstein (2005) • up from 5% during 1993-1995 • Indirect • Perverted incentives, e.g • Size justifies pay: incentive to acquire • Manipulate earnings to sell at high price • Fannie Mae spent $1 billion cleaning up accounting

  25. Going Forward: What Should Be Done ? (1) • Transparency • Outrage constraint currently main check on managerial power • Constraint depends on transparency • SEC must track efforts by pay designers to get around new disclosure rules

  26. 2006 Disclosure Rules (SEC) • Improved summary table reporting • Annual change in actuarial value of pension • Total amount • More detail • More transparent reporting of • Outstanding equity • Post retirement payouts • More detailed rationale for pay package • Result: harder to camouflage compensation

  27. What should be done (2) • Increase shareholder power • Problem: managerial power • Must counterbalance with more shareholder power • Should make it easier to replace directors • SEC could make companies turn proxy material into corporate ballot with both management and shareholder candidates (like political election) • Dramatically lower cost so shareholders can cheaply replace bad directors

  28. Some setbacks • 2003: SEC chair supports “shareholder access” to proxy statement • Business execs pressure White House, SEC chair resigns • But fight is not over • Pressure many companies to adopt “majority vote” for individual directors • So shareholders can “punish” individual directors by withholding votes • Hedge funds becoming active

  29. The future • Further empowering shareholders best hope for improving • Executive compensation • US corporate governance generally THE END

  30. Boards behaving better • CEO pay increases moderating • Kaplan, 2007 • CEO turnover increasing • Kaplan & Minton, 2007

  31. Congress • 1993: Tax: Section 162(m) • 2002: Sarbox • Prohibition on loans • Clawback

  32. 1993: IRC Section 162(m) • Outcry in early 1990s that pay decoupled from performance • Congress: “Non-performance” pay over $1m not deductible by company • At-the-money options qualify as performance pay • Problem: does not address managerial power • Some managers continue to get more than $1m salary • Who is hurt?

  33. Unintended effect of 162(m) • Signals acceptability of • Salary up to $1 million • Large option grants (Congress deems it “performance comp”) • Used to justify total pay increase • Below $1 million salaries rise to $1 million • Option grants skyrocket • Bull market turns options into windfalls • Huge increase in actual non-performance pay

  34. Congress: SarbOx 2002 • Prohibition on loans • Outrage over huge, hidden low-cost loans • 1920s proposal to ban loans resurrected • Effect: disrupts efficient contracting • Clawback provision • Return bonuses, stock proceeds • Following earnings misstatement caused by “misconduct” • Shareholder-serving boards should have done this on their own • Not yet applied

  35. End

  36. Pay without Performance Jesse Fried March 7, 2006 Berkeley For fuller exposition of views on the subject: Pay without Performance (Harvard University Press, 2004)

  37. Going Forward: Making Directors More Accountable to Shareholders • We should make it easier for shareholders to replace directors • E.g., giving shareholders access to corporate ballot would reduce costs of challenging current board • Not a panacea – still collective action problem • but increasing probability of shareholder revolt will improve incentives

  38. Making Directors More Accountable By making boards accountable to shareholders and attentive to their interests, such reform would: • Make reality more like official story of arm’s length negotiations • Improve executive compensation arrangements • Improve corporate governance more generally

  39. Decoupling Pay from Performance (1) • Rise in executive compensation has been justified as necessary to strengthen incentives • Financial economists have applauded: Shareholders should care more about incentives than about the amount paid executives. “It’s not how much you pay, but how” (Jensen & Murphy, 1990) • Institutional investors have accepted higher pay as price of improving managers’ incentives

  40. Decoupling Pay and performance (2) But the devil is in the details: managers’ compensation is less linked to performance than is commonly appreciated. Managers’ own performance does not explain much of the cross-sectional variation in managers’ compensation. Firms could have generated the same increase in incentives at much lower cost, or used the same amount to generate stronger incentives

  41. Decoupling Pay from performance (3) Factors contributing to the weak link between pay and managers’ own performance: (1) The historically weak link between bonus payments and long-term stock returns. (2) The large amounts given through performance-insensitive retirement benefits. (3) The large fraction of gains from equity-based compensation resulting from market-wide and industry-wide movements.

  42. Decoupling Pay from Performance (4) (4) Practices of “back-door re-pricing” and reload options that enable gains even when long-term stock returns are flat. (5) Executives’ broad freedom to unload vested options/restricted stock. (6) “Soft landing” arrangements for pushed out executives that reduce the payoff differences between good performance and failure. And more …

  43. Paying for performance (1) Reduce windfalls from equity-based compensation: • Filter out some or all of the gains resulting from market-wide or sector-wide movements. • Can be done in various ways; indexing is only one option. • Move to restricted stock increases windfalls – restricted stock is an option with an exercise price of zero.

  44. Paying for performance (2) Reduce windfalls from bonus compensation: • Filter out some or all of the improvements in accounting performance resulting from market-wide or sector-wide movements. [E.g., look at increase in earnings relative to peers.]

  45. Paying for performance (3) Tie equity-based compensation to long-term values: • Separate vesting and freedom to unload: require holding for several years after vesting (even until/after retirement). • Prohibit contractually any hedging or other scheme that effectively unloads some of the exposure to firm returns. • Limit the ability of serving executives to time sales.

  46. Paying for performance (4) Tie the performance-based component of non-equity compensation to long-term values: • Assuming it is desirable to link pay to improvement in some accounting measures, don’t link to short-term (e.g., annual) changes – can lead to gaming and distortions or at least to decoupling of pay from long-term changes in value. • Claw-back provisions that reverse payments made on the basis of restated financial figures: “if it wasn’t earned it must be returned.”

  47. Paying for Performance (5) • Rethink termination arrangements: Current arrangements provide “soft landing” in any termination that is not for fault, defined extremely narrowly. This is costly – reduces the payoff difference between good and poor performance. Consider: -- Broadening the definition of “for cause” termination -- Making the severance payment depend on the performance during the executive’s service.

More Related