1 / 39

Intra-Industry Foreign Direct Investment

Intra-Industry Foreign Direct Investment. Laura Alfaro Andrew Charlton Harvard Business School & NBER London School of Economics. What Do We Do in This Paper?.

mae
Download Presentation

Intra-Industry Foreign Direct Investment

An Image/Link below is provided (as is) to download presentation Download Policy: Content on the Website is provided to you AS IS for your information and personal use and may not be sold / licensed / shared on other websites without getting consent from its author. Content is provided to you AS IS for your information and personal use only. Download presentation by click this link. While downloading, if for some reason you are not able to download a presentation, the publisher may have deleted the file from their server. During download, if you can't get a presentation, the file might be deleted by the publisher.

E N D

Presentation Transcript


  1. Intra-Industry Foreign Direct Investment Laura Alfaro Andrew Charlton Harvard Business School & NBER London School of Economics

  2. What Do We Do in This Paper? • Study patterns of vertical and horizontal multinational activity: large new data set of 650,000 multinational subsidiaries in 90+ countries (close to population of MNCs). • Traditionally, the literature has distinguished between two forms of—and motivations for—multinational activity (different effects factor incomes within and across countries). • “Horizontal” FDI: locating production to be closer to customers and avoid trade costs (Markusen, 1984; Brainard, 1993), • “Vertical” FDI: firm’s attempts to take advantage of cross-border factor cost differences (Helpman, 1984; Helpman and Krugman, 1985). • Most research has found that the bulk of FDI is horizontal. • Our results suggest that, due to data limitations, the literature has systematically under-estimated vertical FDI.

  3. Patterns: Firm Data • Consistent with conventional wisdom, • The bulk of multinational activity occurs between the rich nations. • At the 2 digit industry level: horizontal FDI (subsidiaries in the same industry as their parent) >vertical FDI (subsidiaries which supply their parent with inputs). • But … • At the 4 digit level, more vertical activity. • Many of the foreign subsidiaries in the same 2 digit industry as their parent are in fact producing highly specialized inputs into their parents’ production. • This pattern prevails even within developed countries.

  4. Intra Industry FDI • We call these subsidiaries unveiled at higher levels: ‘intra-industry vertical’ FDI. • Qualitatively different to vertical subsidiaries which cross two-digit industry codes (‘inter-industry vertical FDI’). • Supply parent firms with high-skill products • Mostly located in high-skill countries. • These facts are: • At odds with conventional wisdom (more horizontal than vertical) • And… cannot be fully explained by the traditional models of comparative advantage (fragmentation: cost differences). - But …. are consistent with trade data documenting large flows of intra-firm trade in intermediate inputs between rich countries, Bernard et al. (2006).

  5. Discrepancy: Misclassification of Vertical FDI • Significant amount of vertical FDI was misclassified as horizontal: 1. Most vertical FDI is north-north, it has been assumed to be market seeking (horizontal) • Firm level data indicates that these are vertical relationships: parent firms sourcing inputs from their subsidiaries in other northern countries. 2. Skill differences between parent and subsidiaries are small (even within vertical FDI): • This also lends support to horizontal motivations. 3. The vertical nature of these relationships is missed at the 2 digits: • Many subsidiaries are supplying goods to their parents where both the input and the final good are in the same 2 digit SIC.

  6. Explaining Vertical FDI • Both intra and inter industry subsidiaries: provide inputs to parent firms. • But … intra-industry FDI is much harder to explain with the standard theory of vertical FDI (factor cost differences). • ‘Intra-industry vertical FDI’: north-north • Differences between parent and child skill levels are small. • Average proximity between two industries is higher for parent subsidiary pairs: • Proximity: proportion of the intermediate product used directly in the final good ( i.e. raw materials have low proximity variables). • Intra-industry FDI: tendency of multinational firms to own the later stages of the production chain, and outsource the production of early stages and raw materials.

  7. Outline • Introduction and Motivation • Data • Methodology: • Vertical and Horizontal FDI • Patterns and Results: • Discrepancy between Aggregate and Firm Data • Intra-Industry FDI • Explaining Patterns: Comparative Advantage and Proximity • Conclusions

  8. MNC Activity • MNC activities are best measured by firm-level data (Barba Navaretti and Venables, 2005). • Few countries have firm level data. • Researchers tend to use FDI flows from the Balance of Payments statistics as proxy for MNC activity. • Characterization of world multinational activity using firm level data.

  9. The D&B Data Set • Worldbase data: database of both public and private companies in more than 213 countries and independent territories in 2004. Complied by Dun and Bradstreet. • The unit of record is the ‘establishment’ rather than the firm. • 4-digit SIC-1987 code of the primary industry in which firm operates; for several countries, SIC codes of up to 5 secondary industries listed in descending order of importance. • Detailed ownership information: including information about the firm’s family members (no of family members, its domestic parent and its global parent). • Information about the firm’s status (joint-venture, corporation, partnership) and its position in the hierarchy (branch, division, head quarters). • Sales, employment, (some) export, age.

  10. Foreign Ownership • We describe an establishment as foreign owned if it satisfies two criteria: • Foreign owned: must report a global parent firm and that parent firm must be in a different country. • Parents are defined in the data as entities which have legal and financial responsibility for another firm. • Combining the location and ownership information it is possible to identify 650 000+ firms in the database which are owned by a foreign parent.

  11. Comparisons with Other Data: UNCTAD • UNCTAD’s World Investment Report 2004 reports that there are 61,582 parent firms with 926,948 affiliates operating in the world. • In the D&B dataset there are 72,978 parent firms which have 658,188 affiliates in foreign countries reporting to them. • Differences: • Our data is at the plant level, while their data is at the firm level. • UNCTAD data is inflated by a huge number of Chinese observations (424 196): all approved FDI projects registered by the Chinese, but is an overestimate of the number of actual foreign firms.

  12. Comparisons with Other Data: US BEA • BEA’s U.S. Direct Investment Abroad: Benchmark Survey, is a census conducted every 5 years covering virtually the entire population of U.S. MNC’s. • In 2004, BEA reports that sales (employment) by foreign affiliates of U.S. MNCs totaled $3,238 billion (10.02 million employees). • In 2005 the DNB data : sum of all sales (employment) by foreign establishments reporting US parents was $2,795b (10.01 million employees). • The distribution across countries is also consistent.

  13. Comparisons with US BEA

  14. General Patterns • The vast majority of our foreign owned subsidiaries are in richer countries and services.

  15. Measuring Horizontal versus Vertical FDI • Data limitation: we do not observe intra firm trade. • We infer it from information about the goods produced in each of the firm’s establishments and the input-output relationship between those goods. • Hummels, Ishii, and Yi (2001): input-output tables to measure a country’s vertical specialization. • Advantages: • Large amount of data for many countries and industries; value of intra-firm trade not affected by transfer pricing. • Using I-O tables avoids the arbitrariness of classification schemes that divide goods into “intermediate” and other categories; Hummels et al. (2001). • But…identification of vertical subsidiaries as those which supply inputs to their parents relies on a number of assumptions.

  16. Horizontal Complex Vertical Measuring Horizontal and Vertical • We calculate bilateral horizontal and vertical FDI using firm ownership data and U.S. input output matrix. • Horizontal FDI: activity of those foreign owned subsidiaries in the same industry as their parent. • Vertical FDI: activity of foreign owned subsidiaries in industries which are upstream from their parent’s industry (according to the US input output matrix). • Complex FDI: firms satisfy both. • None: If they satisfy neither of these criteria.

  17. Measurement • For each firm: up to six SIC codes for itself and its parent. • Let S be the set of SIC codes of the subsidiary, and let P be the set of SIC codes of the parent. • We use notation x → z to denote any element x being an input into an element z where x Є S and z Є P. • We define x → z if the input output coefficient from the US input output matrix is greater than a threshold level which we vary. We define an owned establishment as: • Horizontal if S and P share any element (if x│x Є S ۷ x Є P) or if the sets are identical (if S=P) • Vertical if any element of S is an input into any element of P ( x│ x → z where x Є S and z Є P) and if the sets are not identical (if S≠P) • Complex if they share any element (if x│ x Є S ۷ x Є P) and if any element of S is an input into any element of P ( x│ x → z where x Є S and z Є P) and if the sets are not identical (if S≠P). • Neither if none of these connections exist.

  18. Methodology: Input-Output Analysis • Threshold: determine the strength of the relationship required to assume that a subsidiary is a supplier to its parent. • Main results: threshold of 0.05 for the ‘total requirements’ coefficient (i.e. the use of a commodity directly and indirectly by an industry). • Robustness: 0.01 and 0.1. • We use an alternative vector of input-output coefficients based on the ‘direct requirements’ (i.e. the use of a commodity directly by an industry) with a threshold of zero. • Analysis of the results: methodology is capturing a supply chain relationship between parents and subsidiaries.

  19. Vertical and Horizontal: Some Results • Within manufacturing subsidiaries (188721), there are 112,939 vertical subsidiaries and 104,057 horizontal subsidiaries (15.8 million versus 11.9 million employees). • We exclude none and complex in the current analysis. • Similar results excluding IO relation within same country. • Results seem consistent related party trade data U.S.

  20. Most Frequent Parent-Subsidiary Horizontal Industry Combinations in DNB Data

  21. Most Frequent Parent-Subsidiary Upstream Vertical Industry Combinations in DNB Data

  22. Firm Level Example: General Motors • General Motors Corporation: 2,248 entities which report it as their ‘global ultimate parent’ • 455 are subsidiaries outside the United States • 123 subsidiaries outside the United States in manufacturing industries. • 68 are ‘horizontal’ subsidiaries (i.e. in the same primary 4 digit SIC code as their parent firm, GM SIC 3711 Motor Vehicles and Passenger Car Bodies) • 42 subsidiaries as being ‘vertical’ FDI (i.e in industries which are inputs in to the parent industry). • The non-manufacturing subsidiaries are primarily dealerships, credit, and insurance institutions.

  23. General Motors: Characteristics of Vertical FDI • Vertical subsidiaries top industries: Specialized Auto Parts (SIC 3714) e.g GM Strasbourg which produces carburetors, pistons, rings, and valves in France; GMI Engineering which produces diesel engine parts in Japan; Vehicle engines (SIC 3519) e.g. Powertrain-Kaiserslautern in Germany. • Average skill intensity of the industries of GM subsidiaries is not significantly different. • The set of GM’s foreign subsidiaries does not include any firms producing what might be called the ‘raw materials’ or ‘low skill inputs’ into the production of automobiles. • GM’s ‘vertical FDI’ is focused on the “penultimate stages” in the vertical production chain.

  24. Vertical Activity: In Rich Countries

  25. 112,939 93,168 65,550 42,783 Vertical: Level of Aggregations • More than half of all vertical subsidiaries are in the same 2 digit industry as their parent but a different 4 digit industry (for example, an automaker (SIC 3711) sourcing specialized auto parts (SIC 3714) from its foreign-owned subsidiary). • The vertical nature of these relationships is missed at the 2 digit level since many subsidiaries are supplying goods to their parents where both the input and the final good are in the same 2 digit SIC code • Lower bound… but linked Input-Output relations.

  26. Vertical FDI: In Close Activities

  27. Vertical Activity: Skill Differences

  28. FDI and Trade Facts • FDI literature: multinational subsidiaries which supply their parents with intermediate goods will be located in low factor costs countries. • Evidence of comparative advantage considerations in MNCs vertical location decisions, Yeaple (2003) and Hanson et al (2001). • Implication: Intra-firm trade will be higher between rich and poor countries than between rich countries. • However …. Bernard, Jensen and Schott’s (2006) find that low income countries have lowshares of intra-firm exports to the US, while high income countries generally report above average intra-firm imports to the U.S. • Implications: intra-firm trade data: lot of vertical FDI between rich countries.

  29. Inter and Intra Industry FDI and Trade Facts • Distinction between intra and inter industry vertical FDI resolves this contradiction. • Analysis of FDI using data with industry information only at the 2 digit focuses exclusively on inter-industry FDI and misses intra-industry vertical FDI. • Firms engaging in inter-industry FDI are more likely to be sourcing low skill inputs from low skill countries: • Validates the results of FDI studies at the 2 digit level. • Including intra-industry vertical FDI (predominantly between rich countries): high share of intra-firm trade flows between rich countries observed in the trade data.

  30. Vertical Patterns • Analyze importance of comparative advantage and the inputs position in the production process in the determination of vertical FDI. • Following Brainard (1997), Yeaple (2003), Carr et al. (2001) FDIijs = 2SumMktSizeij + 3Distanceij +4 CountrySkilli + 5 CountrySkilLij IndustrySkillInts + 6IndustrySKillInts + ijs (1) • i and j: host and parent country, s: industry of the subsidiary. • FDI : bilateral multinational activity in an industry (number of subsidiaries, total sales, total employment). • Distanceij: bilateral distance between the home and host country. • Market size: sum of the GDPs in the host and parent economies. • Country skill: average years of schooling. • Industry Skill Intensity: ratio of non-production to total workers. • Only manufacturing.

  31. Determinants of Multinational Bilateral ActivityMultinational Activity in Each Bilateral Industry Pair--Tobit Regression

  32. Determinants of Multinational Bilateral ActivityMultinational Activity in Each Bilateral Industry Pair--Tobit Regression

  33. Comparative Advantage and Proximity • Interaction between the relative skilled-labor abundance of countries with the skilled-labor intensity of industries. • 2 digits: strong evidence that vertical FDI is driven by comparative advantage, i.e. low skill activities tend to be located in low skill countries. • 4 digit: we find significantly less evidence that vertical FDI is driven by comparative advantage. • Proximity: the position of intermediate inputs in the chain of production contributes to the understanding of the patterns of intra-industry FDI: • Goods closer to raw materials are less likely to be the subject of FDI than intermediate goods which are proximate to the final good.

  34. Measuring Proximity: Requirements • Requirements: ratio of direct/total requirements coefficients. • Direct requirements coefficient, i.e., the amount of the output of industry i used directly as an input into industry j • Total requirements coefficient, i.e, the total amount of industry i used either directly or indirectly in the production of industry j. • The more of the intermediate product used directly in the final good the higher the proximity variable, i.e. raw materials have low proximity variables. • Closeness: absolute difference between the four digit SIC codes of the two products. • Closeness variable takes advantage of the fact that the 1987 SIC groups similar industries together.

  35. Determinants of Multinational Bilateral ActivityMultinational Activity in Each Bilateral Industry Pair--Tobit Regression

  36. Rationales for Proximity • Information advantages associated with the co-ownership of later stages: activities involved in producing proximate inputs may have more in common with the production of the final good than do the activities involved in the production of raw materials, • Firms may be more worried about their intellectual property when the good is closer to their final good. • Monitoring advantage over the penultimate stages of the production. • Maximize quality control over later stages of production. • Contractability characteristics later stages of production (skill intensity, capital intensity, product characteristics…) (Spencer (2006) overview…. Bernard et al. (2006), Antras (2003), Aghion and Tirole (1995))

  37. Conclusions • Firm level data: close to a comprehensive picture multinational activities. • The firm level data: vertical FDI is larger than commonly thought (Hanson et al. 2001, 2005). • Discrepancy: Significant amount of vertical FDI was misclassified. • North-north FDI between parent • Subsidiaries in similarly skilled activities, • More than half of all vertical subsidiaries are only observable at the four-digit level because the inputs they are supplying are so proximate to their parent firm’s final good.

  38. Conclusions • ‘Intra-industry’ vertical subsidiaries: qualitatively different to the inter-industry vertical FDI visible at the two-digit level. • Produce inputs with skill intensity overwhelmingly producing in high skill countries. • Activities not readily explained by the comparative advantage models. • Pattern of intra-industry north-north vertical FDI: decision to outsource versus own the production of intermediate inputs. • Multinationals source raw materials and inputs in early stages of production from outside the firm, • but tend to own the stages of production proximate to their final production giving rise to a class of high-skill intra-industry vertical FDI.

  39. Conclusions: Implications • Level of aggregation: important elements of the pattern of foreign direct investment are missed at the 2 digit level and are not observable without industry data. • Echoing results by Schott (2003) for trade—highlight the importance of shifting away from industry analysis towards more disaggregated data to understand the location decisions firms. • Analysis suggest that foreign activity may be better explained by more complex production processes involving several stages which incorporate both arms length and in sourcing decision. • Future research…

More Related