1 / 21

Prof. Dr. Friedrich Schneider Institut für Volkswirtschaftslehre http://www.econ.jku.at/schneider

Prof. Dr. Friedrich Schneider Institut für Volkswirtschaftslehre http://www.econ.jku.at/schneider . Recht und Ökonomie ( Law and Economics ). LVA-Nr.: 239.203 W S 2012/13 ( 6) Contract Law ( Vertragsrecht ). 1. Contract.

lita
Download Presentation

Prof. Dr. Friedrich Schneider Institut für Volkswirtschaftslehre http://www.econ.jku.at/schneider

An Image/Link below is provided (as is) to download presentation Download Policy: Content on the Website is provided to you AS IS for your information and personal use and may not be sold / licensed / shared on other websites without getting consent from its author. Content is provided to you AS IS for your information and personal use only. Download presentation by click this link. While downloading, if for some reason you are not able to download a presentation, the publisher may have deleted the file from their server. During download, if you can't get a presentation, the file might be deleted by the publisher.

E N D

Presentation Transcript


  1. Prof. Dr. Friedrich Schneider Institut für Volkswirtschaftslehre http://www.econ.jku.at/schneider Recht und Ökonomie (Law and Economics) LVA-Nr.: 239.203 WS 2012/13 (6) Contract Law (Vertragsrecht) Law and Economics

  2. 1. Contract • Contract: agreement that regulates an exchange that is mutually beneficial. • Contracts to give or to make. • Replicable goods or ‘specific’ goods. • General problems: • breach of contract; • information may be asymmetric (one party knows more); • correct incentives to fulfil the contract. Law and Economics

  3. 2. Incompleteness of Contracts • Complete contingent contract (hypothetical) • Incompleteness: Costs of specification: • ex ante, e. g. lawyers fees. • ex post, conflict resolution. • Minimise cost by comparing: • ex ante cost (usually certain) to • ex post cost, usually with presumed probability • assumption: many contracts concluded. Law and Economics

  4. 3. Breach or Re-Negotiation • Suppose seller (S) and buyer (B) contract for 100 washing machines per month for € 35.000. • ‘Daily’ cost of equipment (sunk cost) € 15.000. • sunk costs = incurred costs that cannot be recovered. • Opportunity cost € 25.000 (value of best alternative use of the equipment). • Buyer could re-negotiate contract for a new price of less than € 35.000 (but more than € 25.000). • Post-contractual opportunistic negotiations. Law and Economics

  5. 4. Incompleteness and Contract Law • Reliance on contract law (C. L.) to resolve unexpected (unlikely) occurrences. • Only major or contract specific terms have to be contained in the contract. • Plus some clause: “ … contract is to be governed by the laws of…” • Contract law thus: • serves as ‘default option’; • reduces transaction costs through provision of (efficient) enforcement mechanisms. Law and Economics

  6. 5. Inefficient Contract Laws • Breach of contract reduces profits (welfare). • Possible solution: penalty  • e.g.: “ … delay of delivery (finishing construction, …) leads to a penalty of € … per day (week, …)”; • recovers profits foregone by buyer. • Seller can choose to deliver on time or with delay to maximise his profits  optimal solution for both. • Poor enforcement mechanisms (may) lead to reduced economic activities, reducing welfare. • Uncertain debt recovery (or payment) will lead to request for securities, increases cost. Law and Economics

  7. 6. Efficient Contract Laws • Reduce transaction costs. • Economise on information costs. • Imperfect versus asymmetric information. • Lead to only efficient contract breaches. • Penalty. • Imply efficient reliance. • Avoid opportunistic re-negotiation. • Involve risk minimisation: • precautions to avoid risk; • cost-minimising risk bearing. Law and Economics

  8. 7. Asymmetric Information • Problem: one party in a transaction has more or better information compared to other party  can take advantage of other party’s lack of knowledge market failure (?) • Causes general problems: • Adverse selection. • Moral hazard. • Principal-Agent-Problem Law and Economics

  9. 7. Asymmetric Information (cont.) • Example: consider used car market. • With 100 cars: 50 ‚plums‘ and 50 ‚lemons‘. • Sellers know the quality of car, buyers do not ( asymmetric information). • ‚Plums‘ would be offered for € 6.000, ‚lemons‘ for € 3.000. • Willingness-to-pay (WTP): € 7.200 and € 3.600, respectively. • WTP with no information on quality: € 5.400. • Result: only ‚lemons‘ would be offered no contract. Law and Economics

  10. 8. Adverse Selection Example 1: Bicycle Insurance. • Assume regional differences in theft rates. • Insurance company offers insurance based on average theft rate. • Only people in areas with high theft rates will take out insurance  adverse selection (A. S.). • Result: company will go out of business due to adverse selection (and not due to unbiased selection). Law and Economics

  11. 8. Adverse Selection (cont.) Example 2: Health Insurance. • Insurance company bases rates on average occurrence of health problems. • Individuals know their health status (better), insurance companies do not (or know it lessthan individuals). • Result: Only high risk people will take out insurance. • Solutions to avoid A. S.: • mandatory insurance (e. g. Europe); • ‘health plan’ by firms (e. g. US, also Europe). Law and Economics

  12. 9. Moral Hazard Example: Bicycle Insurance. • Assume probability of theft (also) depends on action, that is care taken by owners (e.g. type of locks). • If no insurance is available: maximum care  • Marginal Costs (MC) of taking care = Marginal Benefit (MB) of taking care. • With insurance: level of care is reduced (change of behaviour)  moral hazard (M. H.). • Holds also for health insurance, fire insurance, ... • Solutions: • deductibles: no full coverage; • try to observe level of care: • rates differ for smokers, houses with sprinkler systems, … Law and Economics

  13. 9.1. Adverse Selection and Moral Hazard • Adverse Selection is due to ‘hidden information’: • one side of the market cannot observe quality. • Moral Hazard is due to ‘hidden action’: • one side of the market cannot observe care. • Lack of information causes inefficiency. • Government action may alleviate the problem only in case of hidden information. • Compulsory insurance. Law and Economics

  14. 10. Signalling • Car example: seller knows more ( signal to buyer): • warranty on used cars; • reputation of seller. • Quality of workers: employee knows more ( signal to employer): • years of school attended; • diploma (‘sheepskin effect’); • additional qualifications; • voluntary work; • … • Objective: reduce the asymmetry in information (at low cost!). Law and Economics

  15. 11. Incentives and Asymmetric Information • Which contract ensures that someone does what I want her/him to do for me? • Also known as ‘Principal–Agent–Problem’: a principal hires one (or more) agent(s), to pursue principal's interests. • Problem: performance of agent(s) not perfectly observable  information asymmetry  incentive scheme / contract? • Examples: employer and employee; owner and manager of company. Law and Economics

  16. 11. Incentives and Asymmetric Information (cont.) • Consider four types of contracts: • Rent; • wage labour; • take-it-or-leave-it; • Sharecropping. Law and Economics

  17. 11.1. Rent • Agent (hirer) pays fixed amount to principal (landowner). • Agent gets all the surplus beyond rent. • Maximum output produced  efficient. • Utility maximizing for agent. • But: agent also bears all the risk. • If agent is more risk averse than the owner the result will be inefficient. • Agent would be willing to give up some income for a reduction in risk. Law and Economics

  18. 11.2. Wage Labour • Principal (employer) pays to agent (worker) a constant amount per unit of effort. • Utility maximizing agent chooses his effort such that marginal product of effort equals marginal cost of effort  efficient. • With asymmetric information: effort cannot be observed by principal (only hours can be observed). • Unless: piece work. Law and Economics

  19. 11.3. Take-it-or-leave-it • Agent (worker) is paid the full amount if he/she chooses the optimum effort level – and zero otherwise. • Outcome: agent chooses this optimal level  efficient. • With asymmetric information: • agent bears all the risk (if payment is based on output); or • effort cannot be observed (payment based on input). Law and Economics

  20. 11.4. Sharecropping • Principal (landowner) and agent each get some fixed proportion of total output. • Since agent gets only a fraction of output he/she will equalize this fraction of marginal product (MP) to the marginal cost (MC). • Leads to an inefficient level of effort (output). • Introducing risk aversion of actors leads to optimum output since both (principal and agent) bear risk. Law and Economics

  21. 12. Conclusions • Results of ‘simple’ economic models may change if one adds: • asymmetry of information; • risk (uncertainty) considerations (risk neutral, risk averse, or risk loving); • behavioural insights (how are decisions actually made?). • If one wants to arrive at recommendations for the concrete design of contracts (more) advanced economic analysis may be required. Law and Economics

More Related