chapter 12 differential games distributed system and impulse control
Download
Skip this Video
Download Presentation
Chapter 12: Differential Games, Distributed System, and Impulse Control

Loading in 2 Seconds...

play fullscreen
1 / 51

chapter12 - PowerPoint PPT Presentation


  • 299 Views
  • Uploaded on

Chapter 12: Differential Games, Distributed System, and Impulse Control More than one decision maker, each having separate objective functions which each is trying to maximize, subject to a set of differential equations. The theory of differential games, Distributed parameter systems,

loader
I am the owner, or an agent authorized to act on behalf of the owner, of the copyrighted work described.
capcha
Download Presentation

PowerPoint Slideshow about 'chapter12' - liam


An Image/Link below is provided (as is) to download presentation

Download Policy: Content on the Website is provided to you AS IS for your information and personal use and may not be sold / licensed / shared on other websites without getting consent from its author.While downloading, if for some reason you are not able to download a presentation, the publisher may have deleted the file from their server.


- - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - E N D - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - -
Presentation Transcript
chapter 12 differential games distributed system and impulse control
Chapter 12: Differential Games, Distributed System, and Impulse Control

More than one decision maker, each having separate

objective functions which each is trying to maximize,

subject to a set of differential equations.

The theory of differential games,

Distributed parameter systems,

Impulse control,

Allow to make discrete changes in the state variables

at selected instants of time in an optimal fashion.

slide2
12.1 Differential Games

Different types of solutions such as minimax, Nash,

Pareto-optimal, along with possibilities of cooperation

and bargaining.

12.1.1 Two Person Zero-Sum Differential Games

which player 1 wants to maximize and player 2 wants

to minimize.

slide3
is the minimax solution.

The necessary conditions for u* and v* ,

is a saddle point of the Hamiltonian function H.

when U=V=E1,

slide4
12.1.2 Nonzero-Sum Differential Games

N players, represent the control

variable for the ith player,

denote the objective function which the ith player

wants to maximize.

A Nash solution:

slide5
Open-Loop Nash Solution

for all

Closed-Loop Nash Solution

we must recognize the dependence of the other

player’s actions on the state variable x. Therefore,

slide6
Interpretation to the adjoint variable i . Any

perturbation x in the state vector causes them to

revise their controls by the amount

12.1.3An Application to the Common-Property

Fishery Resource

Let denote the turnpike (or optimal biomass) level

given by (10.12).

slide7
As shown in Exercise 10.2,

We also assume that

which means that producer 1 is more efficient than

producer 2, i.e., producer 1 can make a positive profit

at any level in the interval , while producer 2

loses money in the same interval, except at where

he breaks even. For both producers make

positive profits.

slide8
As far as producer 1 is concerned, he wants to attain

his turnpike level , if If and if

then from (12.26) producer 2 will fish at his maximum

rate until the fish stock is driven to At this level it is

optimal for producer 1 to fish at a rate which maintains

the fish stock at level in order to keep producer 2

from fishing.

slide9
The Nash solution;

The direct verification involves defining a modified

growth function:

And using the Green’s theorem results of Section

10.1.2. Since by assumption, we have

slide10
for From (10.12) with g replaced by g1, it can

be shown that the new turnpike level for producer 1 is

which defines the optimal policy (12.27)-

(12.28) for producer 1. The optimality of (12.26) for

producer 2 follows easily.

Suppose that producer 1 originally has sole possession of the fishery, but anticipates a rival entry. Producer 1 will switch from his own optimal sustained yield to a more intensive exploitation policy prior to the anticipated entry.

A Nash competitive solution involving N  2 producers

results in the long-run dissipation of economic rents.

slide11
Model for licensing of fishermen let the control variable

vi denote the capital stock of the ith producer and let

the concave function f(vi), with f(0)=0, denote the

fishing mortality function, for i=1,2,…,N. This requires

the replacement of in the previous model by f(vi).

Application of differential games to fishery

management, , Haurie, and Kaitala

(1984,1985) and , Ruusunen,and Kaitala

(1986,1990). Applications to problems in

environmental management, Carraro and Filar (1995).

Applications of marketing in general and optimal

advertising, Bensoussan, Bultez, and Naert(1978),

slide12
Deal, Sethi, and Thompson(1979), Deal(1979),

Jrgensen(1982a), Rao(1984,1990), Dockner and

Jrgensen(1986,1992), Chintagunta and

Vilcassim(1992), Chingtagunta and Jain(1994,1995),

and Fruchter(1999). A survey of the literature is done

by Jrgensen(1982a) and a monograph is written by

Erickson(1991).

For applications of differential games to economics

and management science in general, see the book by

Dockner, Jrgensen , Long, Sorger(2000).

slide13
12.2 Distributed Parameter Systems

Systems in which the state and control variables are

defined in terms of space as well as time dimensions

are called distributed parameter systems and are

described by a set of partial differential or difference

equations.

In the analogous distributed parameter advertising

model we must obtain the optimal advertising

expenditure at every geographic location of interest at

each instant of time, see Seidman, Sethi, and

Derzko(1987). In section 12.2.2 we will discuss a

cattle-ranching model of Derzko, Sethi and

Thompson(1980), in which the spatial dimension

measures the age of a cow.

slide14
Let y denote a one dimensional spatial vector, let t

denote time, and let x(t,y) be a one dimensional state

variable, Let u(t,y) denote a control variable, and let

the state equation be

For t[0,T ] and y [0,h ]. We denote the region [0,T ]x

[0,h] by D, and welet its boundary D be split into two

parts and as shown in Figure 12.1. The initial

conditions will be stated on the part of the boundary

D as

slide15
x0(y) gives the starting distribution of x with respect to

the spatial coordinate y. The function v(t) in (12.33) is

an exogenous breeding function at time t of x when

y=0. In the cattle ranching example in Section 12.2.2,

v(t) measures the number of newly born calves at time

t.

Let F(t,y,x,u) denote the profit rate when x(t,y)=x,

u(t,y)=u at a point (t,y) in D. Let Q(t) be the value of

one unit of x(t,h) at time t and let S(y) be the value of

one unit of x(T,y) at time T.

12 2 1 the distributed parameter maximum principle
12.2.1 The Distributed Parameter Maximum Principle

where xt=x/t andxy= x/y.The boundary conditions

on  are stated for the part of the boundary of D.

whichgives the consistency requirement in the sense

that the price and the salvage value of a unit x(T,h)

must agree.

slide18
We let u*(t,y) denote the optimal control function. Then

the discounted parameter maximum principle requires

that

For all (t,y) D and all u  .

These general forms allow for the function F in (12.2)

to contain arguments such as x/ y, 2x/ y2,etc. It is

also possible to consider controls on the boundary. In

this case v(t) in (12.33) will become a control variable.

12 2 2 the cattle ranching problem
12.2.2 The Cattle Ranching Problem

Let t denote time and y denote the age of an animal.

Let x(t,y) denote the number of cattle of age y on the

ranch at time t. Let h be the age at maturity at which

the cattle are slaughtered. Thus, the set [0,h] is the set

of all possible ages of the cattle. Let u(t,y) be the rate

at which y-aged cattle are bought at time t, where we

agree that a negative value of u denotes a sale.

Subtracting x(t,y) from both sides of (12.42), dividing

by t, and taking the limit as t 0,yields

slide20
The boundary and consistency conditions for x are

given in (12.32)-(12.34). Here x0(y) denotes the initial

distribution of cattle at various ages, and v(t) is an

exogenously specified breeding rate.

Let P(t,y) be the purchase or sale price of a y-aged

animal at time t. Let P(t,h)=Q(t) be the slaughter value

at time t and let P(T,y)=S(y) be the salvage value of a

y-aged animal at the horizon time T. The functions Q

and S represent the proceeds of the cattle ranching

business. Let C(y) be the feeding and corralling costs

for a y-aged animal per unit of time. Let denote

the goal level purchase rate of y-aged cattle at time t.

slide21
The deviation penalty cost is given by

where q is a constant.

subject to the boundary and consistency conditions

(12.38)-(12.40).

slide23
where g is an arbitrary one-variable function and k is a

constant. We will use the boundary conditions to

determine g and k.

We substitute (12.38) into (12.48) and get

This gives

In the region D1 D2.

slide25
(12.50) in the region D1 as the beginning game, which

is completely characterized by the initial distribution x0 .

Also the solution (12.49) in region D3 is the ending

game, because in this region the animals do not

mature, but must be sold at whatever their age is at

the terminal time T.

12 2 3 interpretation of the adjoint function
12.2.3 Interpretation of the Adjoint Function

An animal at age y at time t, where (t,y) is in D1D2,

will mature at time t-y+h. Its slaughter value at that

time is Q(t-y+h). However, the total feeding and

corralling cost in keeping the animal from its age y until

it matures is given by Thus, (t,y) represents

the net benefit obtained from having an animal at age

y at time t.

Interpret the optimal control u* in (12.47). Whenever

(t,y) > P(t,y) , we buy more than the goal level

and when (t,y) < P(t,y), we buy less than the goal

level.

12 3 impulse control
12.3 Impulse Control

Example of an oil producer who pumps oil from a

single well.

where 1 is the starting stock of a new oil well.

12 3 1 the oil driller s problem
12.3.1 The Oil Driller’s Problem

If t = ti , then , which means that we have

abandoned the old well and drilled a new well with

stock equal to v(ti).

where P is the unit price of oil and Q is the drilling cost

of drilling a well having an initial stock of 1.

12 3 2 the maximum principle for impulse optimal control
12.3.2 The Maximum Principle for Impulse Optimal Control

An impulse control variable v , and two associated

functions. The first function is G(x,v,t), which represents

the cost of profit associated with the impulse control.

The sencond function is g(x,v,t), which represents the

instantaneous finite change in the state variable when

the impulse control is applied.

slide32
When t1 = 0 then the equality sign in (vii) should be

replaced by a  sign when i = 1.

Note that condition (vii) involves the partial derivative

of HI with respect to t. Thus, in autonomous problems,

where condition (vii) means that the

Hamiltonian H is continuous at those times where an

impulse control is applied.

slide34
Optimal impulse control at t1 is

After the drilling, which is given by

(12.70).

shown in Figure 12.4, which represent the condition

prior to drilling. Figure 12.4 is

drawn under the assumption that

slide36
From (12.70),

The curve is drawn in Figure 12.5.

BC of the  curve lies in the no drilling region, which is

above thecurve as indicated in Figure 12.5. The part

AB of the  curve is shown darkened and represents

the drilling curve for the problem. The optimal state

trajectory starts from x(0)=1 and decays exponentially

at rate b until it hits the drilling curve AB at point Y.

12 3 4 machine maintenance and replacement
12.3.4: Machine Maintenance and Replacement

T = the given terminal or horizon time,

x(t) = the quality of the machine at time t, 0 x 1; a

higher value of x denotes a better quality,

u(t) = the ordinary control variable denoting the rate of

maintenance at time t ; 0 u G < b/g,

b = the constant rate at which quality deteriorates in

the absence of any maintenance,

g = the maintenance effectiveness coefficient,

 = the production rate per unit time per unit quality of

the machine,

K = the trade-in value per unit quality, i.e., the old machine provides only a credit against the price of the new machine and it has no terminal salvage value,

slide41
C = the cost of new machine per unit quality; C > K,

t1 = the replacementtime; for simplicity we assume at

most one replacement to be optimal in the given

horizon time; see Section 12.3.3,

 = the replacement variable, 0    1;  represents a

fraction of the old machine replaced by the same

fraction of a new machine. This interpretation will

make sense because we will show that v is either 0

or 1 .

slide42
We have assumed that a fraction  of a machine with

quality x has a quality x . Furthermore, we note that

the solution of the state equation will always satisfy

0 x 1, because of the assumption that u Ub/g.

slide44
The solution of (12.84) for t1 < t T is

The switching point is given by solving –1+g=0.

Thus,

provided the right-hand is in the interval (t1,T];

otherwise set We can graph the optimal

maintenance control in the interval (t1,T] as in Figure

12.7. Note that this is the optimal maintenance on the

new machine. To find the optimal maintenance on the

old machine, we need to obtain the value of (t) in the

interval (t1,T] .

slide46
and compute the time

which makes

In plotting Figure 12.8, we have assumed that 0<(0)

<1. This is certainly the case, if T is not too large so

that

slide47
As in the oil driller’s problem, we obtain (t) by using

(12.88). From (12.92), we have v*(t1)=1 and, therefore,

(t1) =K from (12.85) and from (12.83). Since

gK  1 from (12.96), we have

and, thus, u*(t1)=0 from (12.90). That is, zero

maintenance is optimal on the old machine just before

it is replaced. Since from (12.97), we have

from Figure 12.7. That is, full maintenance is

optimal on the new machine at the beginning.

slide49
AB represents the replacement curve. The optimal

trajectory x*(t) is shown by CDEFG under the

assumption that t1 > 0 and t1< t2, where t2 is the

intersection point of curves (t) and (t), as shown in

Figure 12.8.

Figure 12.9 has been drawn for a choice of the

problem parameters such that t1= t2.

slide51
Using (t1)=K obtained above and the adjoint equation

(12.84), we have

Using (12.100) in (12.90), we can get u*(t),t[0,t1].

and the switching point by solving –1+g=0.

If  0, then the policy of no maintenance is optimal

in the interval [0,t1]. If > 0, the optimal maintenance

policy for the old maintenance is

In plotting Figure 12.7 and 12.8,we have assumed

>0.