1 / 28

Economic method of multiple production

Economic method of multiple production. Multiple Use of Forests Economic Analysis Example: Belgrade Forest (Ömer EKER , 2007) Vertical Products Horizontal Products/ Joint Production Technically Fixed Proportion Technically Variable Proportion.

lesley
Download Presentation

Economic method of multiple production

An Image/Link below is provided (as is) to download presentation Download Policy: Content on the Website is provided to you AS IS for your information and personal use and may not be sold / licensed / shared on other websites without getting consent from its author. Content is provided to you AS IS for your information and personal use only. Download presentation by click this link. While downloading, if for some reason you are not able to download a presentation, the publisher may have deleted the file from their server. During download, if you can't get a presentation, the file might be deleted by the publisher.

E N D

Presentation Transcript


  1. Economic method of multiple production • Multiple Use of Forests • Economic Analysis • Example: Belgrade Forest (Ömer EKER , 2007) • Vertical Products • Horizontal Products/ Joint Production • Technically Fixed Proportion • Technically Variable Proportion

  2. Forests besides producing timber, also provide environments where people pursue different activities (recreation, carbon sink). • Conflicting demands create controversies between commercial forestry and environmental preservation • Economic perspective helps in solving such dilemma by maximising the total net benefit both from forestry and the remaining forest environment.

  3. Multiple use • In restricted economic term: simply means that forests and wildlands have more than one use and the typical forestry enterprise produces more than one product. • Multiple use is defined as the management of various land resources so that they are used in the combination that will best fulfill the needs of people without impairing productivity of soil (Reiske, 1966).

  4. Multiple use • emphasizes sustainable production of goods and services • The objective is to produce mix of market and non market goods that maximizes the value of forests to society. • Production of secondary good is tolerable as long as it does not conflict with primary objective. Timber harvests, that improve the conditions of forests are acceptable . While timber harvest could be decreased to increase recreation • Multiple use is by no means an assemblage of single uses. It requires conscious, co-ordinated management of the various renewable resources, each with the other, without impairment of the productivity of the land.

  5. Multiple use contd • There are two approaches of multiple use (Gregory, 1987): (1) applying to larger areas - range, working circle, entire forest area with specific area devoted to a single (or at least a primary) use. Under this interpretation, the manager will settle on a primary use for each specific area. Secondary uses would be permitted in the area only if they do not interfere with the primary objective. Timber production, for example, might not be prohibited on a designated recreation area, but would not be permitted to interfere with recreational use. (2) the alternative approach makes no area subdivision and declares no primary uses. Instead, the objective of management is assumed to be the maximisation of social returns, measured in whatever units are deemed appropriate. Following this approach, management should produce the combination of products that would maximise net return to the owners.

  6. Biesterfeldt and Boyce (1978) points to the difficulty with the lack of a practical method for coordinating production of multiple benefits. Foresters can, for example, provide wildlife habitat, recreation opportunities, and a high quality of water, while also producing commercial crops of timber. However, they have not known how to harmonise action on a management unit to achieve the most desirable combination of benefits. Most research and management actions deal with primary benefits; secondary benefits are usually ignored or permitted to accrue as they may.

  7. Belgrade Forest • Belgrade Forest lies on north of the Istanbul peninsula, Turkey • Total area: 5 442 hectares, with 71 types of birds, and 18 mammals. Hunting is prohibited and 103 ha is reserved for deer breeding and their protection • 4.7% of the total area is planned for recreation • case study: data about timber sales, number of annual visits to the recreation area and entry fee charges were collected • Information about the identification of the forest uses – gathered from Forest Management Plan • carbon storage and recreation value formulas were applied in order to find the total value of the forest utilities.

  8. As a first option, the forest is allowed to grow untouched for carbon storage without considering recreation and timber value. It is expected that the increment will continue for 100 years. carbon storage value/hectare is £425 (using £20/ton carbon). • As a second option, suppose that one-third of the forest area is felled for recreation. In this case, one-third of the carbon benefit which is calculated in the first option will be lost. This is £142 per hectare (425/3). Therefore, the carbon storage value will decrease to £283 per hectare. There is also a loss due to decay of existing carbon. If the carbon cost is £20 per tonne the discounted cost of allowing a cubic metre timber to decay will be about £5. For the measured area (29.42 ha) which has a standing volume of 5,560 m3, this value is £315 per hectare.

  9. In order to estimate the timber benefit gained from 1/3 of the area, timber sale values for year 1995 were used in the calculations. Approximately £236 per hectare was obtained from the timber sales. • Data about number of visits and entry fees for the estimation of the recreation value were collected from the forest enterprise. The entry fee and number of annual visits per hectare were taken as 25 pence/person and 4500 visits.

  10. the results of the second option the total value =£22,533/ ha. • The second option is viable as long as either the number of visits (y) does not fall below 45 per hectare per year, or when the entry price (z) is not less than 0.25 pence.

  11. Interpretation of result • When the second option’s result is compared to the first option’s result, it is suggested that the second option is more beneficial than the first one. In other words, felling one-third of the forest area for recreation would allow about 53 (22,533/425) times more benefit than using the area only for carbon storage.

  12. Conclusion: • According to the results the forest for timber production, carbon storage and recreation supplies more benefits than using it only for carbon storage. Increasing the amount of the recreation area will provide short term financial returns to the forest enterprise without waiting for a long harvesting time. However, consideration should also be given to the limited compatibility between timber production and recreation uses. In the short term commercial recreation is desirable so that initial forestry investment costs for timber production can be repaid. However, in the long term, if recreational use is increased in the area timber production and its related revenues will decline. Therefore, this should also be taken into account during forest land planning and forest resource allocation for the multiple uses.

  13. Integration in Production • Enterprises combined for multiple-production is termed as integration: vertical and horizontal. Enterprises representing successive links in the economic chain of production in a firm are when combined, the firm is vertically integrated e.g., firm engaged in growing trees and logging. • Enterprises that use same inputs are combined within a firm, the firm is said to be horizontally integrated e.g., firm producing lumber and pulp. • Sometimes a single firm can both be vertically and horizontally integrated.

  14. Vertical Products • For example, the firm may decide to produce X units of lumber because it maximises the profits of the firm. For this output of lumber Y units of logs may be required. Therefore the logging enterprise will plan to harvest Z units of forest area to meet this requirement. Thus stumpage, logs and lumber are vertically related products of an integrated firm. The usual practice is that the output of the first product in the production chain, that is thought to maximize profit, is planned to be produced. • Under perfect competitive markets for each product the appropriate policy for the firm is to maximize profit of each enterprise by producing at the point where his marginal revenue equals his marginal cost.

  15. Horizontal Products/ Joint Production • As long as the two products are produced by entirely separate processes no special problems arise. Problems arise when the same production facility is used to produce two or more products. This is the case of joint production. Joint production can be of two types – production in technically fixed proportions (wheat and straw, beef and hides etc.) and in technically variable proportions (sawlogs and pulpwood, herbs and stumps etc.)

  16. Technically Fixed Proportion • With technically fixed proportions, the product combinations hold a constant ratio to each other. If the combinations are plotted on a diagram it will take a shape of a straight line passing through the origin as shown in fig.1 by OD.

  17. Joint production with technically fixed proportions can always be reduced to the single product case. E.g., in a particular sawmill one ton of pulpwood chips can be produced with every 1400 board feet of sawnwood, the problem of joint production can be solved by treating this as a “combination” product. The total cost and revenue picture might appear as in fig.2, where single cost and revenue curves are used while the horizontal axis shows quantities of both lumber and chips at all relevant outputs. The profit maximizing solution is obtained exactly as before, and a full set of total cost curves can be derived.

  18. In purely competitive situations no particular treatment of the firm’s demand is necessary. But, from the standpoint of industry, market analysis, and pricing the two jointly produced products may be quite different. Determination of price of jointly produced goods is shown in fig 3. In the fig. Ds represent demand for sawlogs and Dc shows demand for chips. Then the vertical summation of these curves represented by Dsc in the fig. indicates industry’s total demand curve for sawlogs and chips. If the supply curve for the combination product is represented by Ssc, the combination price is determined at Psc. Accordingly the individual price for sawlogs and chips is determined at Ps and Pc respectively as shown in the fig.

  19. Technically Variable Proportion • In this case, although joint use of some productive factor or service is involved in production, the proportion in which the products can be produced may vary. For example a given hectare of forest can yield sawntimber and pulpwood in varying proportions. With given inputs, output of one product can be increased by reducing the output of other product/s. This is shown in fig 1 assuming that it is possible to produce any combination among A, B, C etc. with given inputs. If we join all these possible combinations we get a curve as shown in fig 4 called production possibility curve (PPC). With increase in inputs i.e. the cost of production PPC shifts to the right hand side, showing more outputs as shown in the fig. Now if the products are sold in the market firm will get revenue. Different combinations of products will give different level of revenue to the producer. Joining all combinations of the products which give equal revenues we get a curve called isorevenuecurve. Under perfect competition as price and therefore price ratio of the products is fixed, isorevenue curves will be straight line and parallel to each other as shown in fig 5.

  20. Combining these isorevenue curves with previous set of PPCs we get a diagram as in fig.6. Each tangency point in the fig. is the point where revenue is maximum for any particular cost outlay. If we join all these points of tangency we get a curve called expansion path and a rational producer will always operate in such a manner as to produce a combination which lie on this curve. Now the problem is which combination is the optimum?

  21. The complete solution is shown in fig 7, which is a combination of fig 6 with the resulting total cost / total revenue curves. The profit maximizing combination can be read from point on the expansion path that falls directly below the point where the slopes of the total cost and total revenue curves are equal.

  22. In this case also average costs for either product can not be determined. An average cost of lumber production or pulpwood production does not exist. For the sake of convenience, one could construct a pseudo-average cost diagram by employing a device similar to that of fig 7. But marginal costs do exist and can be determined for either product. Because the marginal cost equation for either product will contain the output of the jointly produced product as a variable, the two marginal cost curves must be solved simultaneously. Algebraically this can be calculated as below: Given the total cost as a function of the output of two products, X and Y, TC = f (X,Y) then the marginal costs of X and Y become, respectively, MCX = ∂(TC)/∂X and MCY = ∂(TC)/∂Y

  23. Thanks for your attention

More Related