1 / 53

Auctions

Auctions. Strategic Situation. You are bidding for an object in an auction. The object has a value to you of $20. How much should you bid? Depends on auction rules presumably. Review: Second Price Auctions. Suppose that the auction is a second-price auction High bidder wins

legault
Download Presentation

Auctions

An Image/Link below is provided (as is) to download presentation Download Policy: Content on the Website is provided to you AS IS for your information and personal use and may not be sold / licensed / shared on other websites without getting consent from its author. Content is provided to you AS IS for your information and personal use only. Download presentation by click this link. While downloading, if for some reason you are not able to download a presentation, the publisher may have deleted the file from their server. During download, if you can't get a presentation, the file might be deleted by the publisher.

E N D

Presentation Transcript


  1. Auctions

  2. Strategic Situation • You are bidding for an object in an auction. • The object has a value to you of $20. • How much should you bid? • Depends on auction rules presumably

  3. Review: Second Price Auctions • Suppose that the auction is a second-price auction • High bidder wins • Pays second highest bid • Sealed bids • We showed (using dominance) that the best strategy was to bid your value. • So bid $20 in this auction.

  4. Review: English Auctions • An English (or open outcry) auction is one where bidders shout bids publicly. • Auction ends when there are no higher bids. • Implemented as a “button auction” in Japan • Implemented on eBay through proxy bidding.

  5. What to Bid • Again, suppose you value the object at $20. • Dominance says to drop out when bid = value. • The fact that bidding strategies are the same in the two auction forms means that they are strategically equivalent.

  6. Revenues • How much does the seller earn on the auction? • Depends on the distribution of values. • Suppose that there are 2 bidders and values are equally likely to be from $0 to $100. • The seller earns an amount equal to the expected losing bid.

  7. Order Statistics • The seller is interested in the expected value of the lower of two draws from 0-100. • This is called the second order statistic of the distribution. • We will sometimes write this as E[Vk(n)] where the k denotes the order (highest, 2nd highest, etc.) of the draw and (n) denotes the number of draws. • So we’re interested in E[V2(2)]

  8. Order Statistics of Uniform Distributions • There order statistics have simple regularity properties • The mean of a uniform draw from 0-100 is 50. • Note the mean could be written as E[V1(1)]. 100 0 50

  9. Two Draws • Now suppose there are two draws. • What are the first and second order statistics? 100 0 66 33

  10. Key Observation • With uniform distributions, the order statistics evenly divide the number line into n + 1 equal segments. • Let’s try 3 draws: 1st 3rd 2nd 50 0 75 100 25

  11. Generalizing • So in general, • E[Vk(n)] = 100* (n – k + 1)/(n + 1) • So revenues in a second price or English auction in this setting are: • E[V2(n)] = 100 * (n – 1)/(n + 1) • As the number of bidders grows large, the seller’s revenues increase • As the number of bidders grows unbounded, the seller earns all the surplus, i.e. 100!

  12. First Price Auctions • Now suppose you have a value of $20 and are competing with one other bidder in a first-price auction • You don’t know the exact valuation of the other bidder. • But you do know that it is randomly drawn from 0 to 100. • How should you bid?

  13. Setting Up the Problem • As usual, you want to bid to maximize your expected payoff • But now you need to make a projection about the strategy of the other bidder • Presumably this strategy depends on the particular valuation the bidder has. • Let b(v) be your projection for the bid of the other bidder when his valuation is v.

  14. Bidder’s Problem • Choose a bid, B, to maximize expected profits. • E[Profit] = (20 – B) x Pr(B is the highest bid) • What is Pr(B is the highest bid)? • It is Pr(B > b(v))

  15. What is Pr(B > b(v))? b(v) B v I lose I win b-1(B)

  16. Conjectures about b(v) • Suppose that I believe that my rival’s strategy is to bid a constant fraction of his value • Then b(v) = av • Where a is some fraction • I win whenever • B >= av • Or, equivalently • v <= B/a • So Pr(B > b(v)) becomes: • Pr( v <= B/a) = B/100a

  17. Bidder’s Problem Revisited • So now I need to choose B to maximize • E[Profit] = (20 – B)(B/100a) • Optimize in the usual way: • (1/100a) x (20 – 2B) = 0 • Or B = 10 • So I should bid 10 when my value is 20.

  18. Other Values • Suppose my value is V? • E[Profit] = (V – B)(B/100a) • Optimize in the usual way: • (1/100a) x (V – 2B) = 0 • Or B = V/2 • So I should always bid half my value.

  19. Equilibrium • My rival is doing the same calculation as me. • If he conjectures that I’m bidding ½ my value • He should bid ½ his value (for the same reasons) • Therefore, an equilibrium is where we each bid half our value.

  20. Uncertainty about my Rival • This equilibrium we calculated is a slight variation on our usual equilibrium notion • Since I did not exactly know my rival’s payoffs in this game • I best responded to my expectation of his strategy • He did likewise

  21. Bayes-Nash Equilibrium • Mutual best responses in this setting are called Bayes-Nash Equilibrium. • The Bayes part comes from the fact that I’m using Bayes rule to figure out my expectation of his strategy.

  22. Comments • In this setting, dominant strategies were not enough • What to bid in a first-price auction depends on conjectures about how many rivals I have and how much they bid. • Rationality requirements are correspondingly stronger.

  23. Revenues • How much does the seller make in this auction? • Since the high bidder wins, the relevant order statistic is E[V1(2)] = 66. • But since each bidder only bids half his value, my revenues are • ½ x E[V1(2)] = 33 • Notice that these revenues are exactly the same as in the second price or English auctions.

  24. Revenue Equivalence • Two auction forms which yield the same expected revenues to the seller are said to be revenue equivalent • Operationally, this means that the seller’s choice of auction forms was irrelevant.

  25. More Rivals • Suppose that I am bidding against n – 1 others, all of whom have valuations equally likely to be 0 to 100. • Now what should I bid? • Should I shade my bid more or less or the same? • In the case of second-price and English auctions, it didn’t matter how many rivals I had, I always bid my value • What about in the first-price auction?

  26. Optimal Bidding • Again, I conjecture that the others are bidding a fraction a of their value. • E[Profit] = (V – B) x Pr(B is the high bid) • To be the high bid means that I have to beat bidder 2. • Pr( B >= b(v2)) = B/100a • But I also have to now beat bidders 3 through n.

  27. Probability of Winning • So now my chance of winning is • B/100a x B/100a x …B/100a • For n – 1 times. • Or equivalently • Pr(B is the highest) = [B/100a]n-1

  28. Bidder 1’s optimization • Choose B to maximize expected profits • E[Profit] = (V – B) x Pr(B is highest) • E[Profit] = (V – B) x [B/100a]n-1 • E[Profit] = (1/100a)n-1 x (V – B) x [B]n-1 • Optimizing in the usual way: • (1/100a)n-1 x ((n-1)V – nB) [B]n-2 = 0 • So the optimal bid is • B = V x (n-1)/n

  29. Equilibrium • I bid a proportion of my value • But that proportion is (n-1)/n • As I’m competing against more rivals, I shade my bid less. • Since all my rivals are making the same calculation, in equilibrium everyone bids a fraction (n-1)/n of their value.

  30. Revenues • How much does the seller make in this auction? • The relevant order statistic is E[V1(n)] = 100* n/(n + 1) • But eveyone shades by (n-1)/n so • Revenues = (n-1)/n x E[V1(n)] • Revenues = 100 x (n-1)/(n+1)

  31. Comments • Revenues are increasing in the number of bidders • As that number grows arbitrarily large, the seller gets all the surplus, i.e. 100! • How does this compare to the English or Second-Price auction?

  32. Comparing Revenues • First-price: • R = (n-1)/n x E[V1(n)] • R = 100 x (n-1)/(n+1) • Second-price: • R = E[V2(n)] • R = 100 x (n-1)/(n+1) • The auctions still yield the same expected revenues.

  33. Revenue Equivalence Theorem • In fact, revenue equivalence holds quite generally • Consider any auction which: • Allocates the object to the highest bidder • Gives any bidder the option of paying zero • Then if bidders know their values • Values are uncorrelated • Values are drawn from the same distribution • Then all such auctions are revenue equivalent!

  34. Implications • This means that we can determine the revenues quickly and easily for all sorts of auctions • Consider an all-pay auction • Bidders submit cash payments to the seller (bribes) • The bidder submitting the highest bribe gets the object • The seller keeps all the bribe money • This auction auction yields the same revenues as an English auction.

  35. Other Strange Auction forms • Suppose that all bidders submit bribes to the auctioneer • The object is awarded to the person paying the highest bribe • And the seller gives back the bribe of the winner, but keeps all the others • This is also revenue equivalent.

  36. Optimal Auctions • Revenue equivalence says that the form of the auction does not affect how much money the seller makes. • But there are other tools the seller has to make money.

  37. One Bidder Auctions • Suppose that the seller is running an auction that attracts only one bidder. • What should he do? • If he goes with the usual auction forms, he’ll make nothing since the second highest valuation for the object is zero.

  38. Monopoly • Since the seller is a monopoly provider of the good, maybe some tricks from monopoly theory might help. • Suppose a monopolist faced a linear demand curve and could only charge a single price • What price should he charge?

  39. Monopoly Problem P Demand curve Q

  40. Monopoly Problem • The monopolist should choose p to maximize profits • Profits = P x Q(P) – C(Q(P)) • Or equivalently, the monopolist could choose Q to maximize profits • Profits = P(Q) x Q – C(Q) • P(Q) is the inverse demand function • Optimizing in the usual way, we have: • MR = MC

  41. Monopoly Problem P Marginal Revenue P* MC Q Q*

  42. Back to Auctions • What is the demand curve faced by a seller in a one bidder auction? • One can think of the “quantity” as the probability of making a sale at a given price. • So if the seller asks for $100, he will make no sales. • If he asks for $0, he will sell with probability = 1 • If he asks $50, he will sell with probability .5

  43. Auction/Monopoly Problem P 100 50 0 1 Q = Pr of sale 1/2

  44. Auction/Monopoly Problem P Q = 1 – F(p) 100 50 0 1 Q = Pr of sale 1/2

  45. Demand Curve • So the demand curve is just the probability of making a sale • Pr(V > P) • If we denote by F(p) the probability that V <=p, then • Q = 1 – F(p) • But we need the inverse demand curve to do the monopoly problem the usual way. • P = F-1(1 – Q)

  46. Auction/Monopoly Problem • Now we’re in a position to do the optimization. • The seller should choose a reserve price to maximize his expected profits • E[Profits] = p x (1 – F) • Equivalently, the auctioneer chooses a quantity to maximize • E[Profits] = F-1(1 – Q) x Q

  47. Optimization • As usual the optimal quantity is where MR = MC • But MC is zero in this case • So the optimal quantity is where MR = 0

  48. Auction/Monopoly Problem P Marginal Revenue 100 P* 0 1 Q = Pr of sale Q*

  49. So what is Marginal Revenue? • Revenue = F-1(1 – Q) x Q • Marginal Revenue = F-1(1 – Q) – Q/f(F-1(1 – Q)) • where f(p) is (approximately) the probability that v = p • Now substitute back: • P – (1 – F(p))/f(p) = 0

  50. Uniform Case • In the case where valuations are evenly distributed from 0 to 100 • F(p) = p/100 • f(p) = 1/100 • So • P – (1 – P) = 0 • Or • P = 50!

More Related