1 / 29

STR 421

STR 421. Economics of Competitive Strategy Michael Raith Spring 2007. Today’s class. 5. Strategic commitments 5.1 Logic of commitment 5.2 Strategic commitments and competition 5.3 Entry deterrence 5.4 Entry strategies (next week). Strategic commitments.

kellsie
Download Presentation

STR 421

An Image/Link below is provided (as is) to download presentation Download Policy: Content on the Website is provided to you AS IS for your information and personal use and may not be sold / licensed / shared on other websites without getting consent from its author. Content is provided to you AS IS for your information and personal use only. Download presentation by click this link. While downloading, if for some reason you are not able to download a presentation, the publisher may have deleted the file from their server. During download, if you can't get a presentation, the file might be deleted by the publisher.

E N D

Presentation Transcript


  1. STR 421 Economics of Competitive Strategy Michael Raith Spring 2007

  2. Today’s class 5. Strategic commitments 5.1 Logic of commitment 5.2 Strategic commitments and competition 5.3 Entry deterrence 5.4 Entry strategies (next week)

  3. Strategic commitments • Keeping your options open may always seem to be a good thing. • But sometimes, making irreversible commitments can have important strategic value. • Example: Hernán Cortés’ decision to sink his ships upon landing in Mexico.

  4. When the decision to invade Mexico is easy to reverse:

  5. Commitment is about limiting your options in the future If Cortés sinks his ships before Montezuma decides what to do:

  6. Commitments as strategic moves

  7. What makes a move a commitment? Commitments must be… • credible • …a problem with NATO’s “massive retaliation” strategy during Cold War • Greatest credibility when decisions are irreversible, i.e. involve sunk costs • Alternatively: build up a reputation for credibility • visible • understandable

  8. Commitment vs. flexibility • The cost of commitment: having fewer options is bad if you misjudge the situation or another player • What if Montezuma’s cost of fighting is lower than expected? • Sometimes it’s best to wait and decide later: • E.g. learn about future market conditions and then make decision based on new information

  9. Today’s class 5. Strategic commitments 5.1 Logic of commitment 5.2 Strategic commitments and competition 5.3 Entry deterrence 5.4 Entry strategies

  10. Example: investing in lower costs under price competition • Modified example from second week: American and Southwest in L.A. – Vegas market • MC=60, daily demand: • American’s demand: QA = 120 – 1.5 pA + pS • Southwest’s demand: QS = 120 – 1.5 pS + pA • Best responses: • American’s best response: pA = 70 + 1/3 pS • Southwest’s best response: pS = 70 + 1/3 pA • Nash equilibrium: pA = pS = $105/ticket • Profits: πA = πS = $3038/day

  11. Invest to lower MC? • Suppose American can lower its MC by 5% (from 60 to 57) by investing $340K. Good idea? • Suppose: • 1 flight/day, 360 days/year • 20% discount rate, “quick and dirty” method • Then investment is profitable if it leads to increase in profit per flight of $340K*.2/360 = $189 • Let’s see if that’s the case.

  12. Cost reduction and price changes • Scenario 1: American charges same price => Southwest too • πA = (105 – 57)(120 – 1.5 * 105 + 105) = 3240 • Increase by 3240 – 3038 = 202 • Looks profitable! • Problem: not a Nash equilibrium given lower MC • Scenario 2: Lower MC => Charge lower price • American’s profit πA = (pA – 57)(120 – 1.5 * pA + 105) • Best response: pA = 68.5 + 1/3 pS, at pS = 105: pA = 103.50 • American’s profit = 3243, increase by 205 • Even better!

  13. The strategic effect of lowering MC • If American cuts price, Southwest will cut price too, etc. • What is new equilibrium? • American’s new best response: pA = 68.5 + 1/3 pS • Southwest’s best response is unchanged: pS = 70 + 1/3 pA • New equilibrium: pA = 103.31, pS = 104.44 • American’s profit: • With new prices: πA = 3217 • Increase by 3217 – 3038 = 180 < 189 • Investment not profitable! • Conclusion: Incentive to cut price triggers response by Southwest that makes investment less profitable

  14. Illustration: Investment by American to lower MC (tough commitment, price competition):

  15. When does this happen? • American’s investment is a tough commitment = American’s incentive to cut price shifts Southwest’s demand down • Competition in prices is case of strategic complements = each firm’s best response is increasing in other’s price • When firms compete in prices, tough commitments have a negative strategic effect

  16. Soft commitments and price competition • A soft commitment benefits your competitor once you adjust price or quantity • Why would you want to do that?? • Example: the GM Card of 1992 • Cardholders earn credit equal to 5% of charge volume, can be applied to purchase of GM cars • Most appealing to those who are already inclined to buy GM

  17. How the GM card works: • Suppose initially GM and Ford charge 20,000 for a car • Now GM gives loyal customers (through the card) a rebate of $2,000 and increases the list price by $1,000 • A bit counterintuitive… • How should Ford respond? Go after GM’s loyal customers or charge Ford’s loyal customers more? • Positive strategic effect!

  18. Soft commitments can be good for you • When firms compete in prices, soft commitments have a positive strategic effect • An investment that is unprofitable if you ignore the strategic effect might be profitable if you take it into account • Soft commitments: anything that reduces incentive to cut price: most-favored customer clauses, moves to increase loyalty, differentiation • Bottom line: to get wimpy response, act wimpy. • With these strategies, you are even better off if others copy you

  19. Next: investing in lower costs under quantity competition • Shrimp game again: in Nash equilibrium, • q = 50 for each, P = 15, π = 500 for each • Suppose Arnold can reduce MC from 5 to 4, and… • …investment profitable if profit increases by at least 60 • With previous quantities: πA = (15 – 4)*50 = 550, increase by 50 => not profitable • But Arnold would want to produce more: • New best response: qA = 102.5 – (qB + qC)/2, • Given qB = qC= 50: qA = 52.5 => Price = 14.5 • πA = (14.5 – 4)*52.50 = 551.25 • Still not profitable

  20. Strategic effect with quantity competition • But Beatrice and Charlotte want to produce less if Arnold produces more = case of strategic substitutes • Best responses: qA = 102.5 – (qB+qC)/2, qB = 100 – (qA+qC)/2, qC = 100 – (qA+qB)/2 • Solve for q’s: qA = 53.75, qB = 48.75, qC = 48.75 • Arnold’s profit: 578 => investment profitable! • So, when firms compete in quantities (think: capacity investments), tough commitments have a positive strategic effect • To get wimpy response, act tough

  21. Illustration: Investment by Arnold to lower MC (tough commitment, quantity competition):

  22. Conclusion • In assessing profitability of long-run decisions, consider strategic effects as well! Need to ask: • When I adjust price or quantity, is my competitor worse off (tough commitment) or better off (soft commitment)? • Is competition in prices (short run) or quantities (capacities, long run)? • More generally, strategic complements vs. substitutes: e.g. if I advertise more, will you advertise more, or less?

  23. Today’s class 5. Strategic commitments 5.1 Sequential games and the logic of commitment 5.2 Strategic commitment and competition 5.3 Entry deterrence 5.4 Entry strategies

  24. Three possible scenarios facing an incumbent in a market • No one wants to enter your industry anyway • Recall barriers to entry from Section 2 of lecture • Whatever you do, entry will occur anyway • You have little choice, just be prepared • Borderline case: entry likely if you do nothing, but might be deterred depending on what you do today • Idea: invest to keep entrants out • We are talking about (over)investments to be tough • Usually concerned with own profit only, here also with entrants profit

  25. Logic of preemption • Suppose that • if firm 1 does nothing, firm 2 enters at cost C • both firms earn duopoly profits • if firm 1 expands at cost C, no entry occurs • firm 1 remains monopolist, but has paid C • Which is better for firm 1? Expansion, because • Monopoly profit > Sum of duopoly profits • Therefore, gain from preemption = Monopoly profit – C - duopoly profit > Duopoly profit – C = entrant’s net gain > 0 • “Efficiency effect”: Incumbent’s gain from preemption > entrant’s gain from entry

  26. Examples of this effect at work: • Sleeping patents: buy a competing patent and let it sleep, to keep others from using it • Payoff of generics producers: e.g. in 1998, Abbott Labs paid Zenith and Geneva, two generics producers, $2M and $4.5M per month, respectively, not to produce.

  27. Preemption strategies • Preemption strategies work like first-mover advantages • But here, an incumbent, facing threat of entry, actively invests in FMA • Examples • Excess capacity (i.e. relative to optimal capacity for “undisturbed” monopolist) • Geographic preemption/brand proliferation • E.g. frequency of flights • Advertise, create switching costs, etc., see Lecture 2 • Commitment is essential for preemption to work!

  28. Pricing strategies to deter entry: • Predatory pricing: = lower price to drive competitor out of market; then raise price to recoup losses • Problems: • Fighting very costly • If entry is economically profitable, someone else might enter • Hard to get convicted, but also rarely a good business strategy • Limit pricing: = deliberately lower price to signal that you have low costs or that demand is low. • Makes sense only if outsiders don’t know your costs. Otherwise, what you do today is irrelevant

  29. Antitrust constraints • Section 2 Sherman Act prohibits attempts to monopolize market • Note: does not prohibit monopoly as such • “Naturally” acquired market power or foul play? • Actions consistent with efficient competition or monopolization look the same, e.g. aggressive pricing vs. predation • Extremely difficult to decide, e.g. Microsoft case • All strategies above have been focus of antitrust cases • When big firms act tough, small firms likely to sue • Litigation very costly for both sides.

More Related