1 / 68

Economic Growth I: Capital Accumulation and Population Growth

PART III Growth Theory: The Economy in the Very Long Run. Economic Growth I: Capital Accumulation and Population Growth. Chapter 8 of Macroeconomics , 8 th edition, by N. Gregory Mankiw ECO62 Udayan Roy. The Solow-Swan Model. This is a theory of macroeconomic dynamics

juana
Download Presentation

Economic Growth I: Capital Accumulation and Population Growth

An Image/Link below is provided (as is) to download presentation Download Policy: Content on the Website is provided to you AS IS for your information and personal use and may not be sold / licensed / shared on other websites without getting consent from its author. Content is provided to you AS IS for your information and personal use only. Download presentation by click this link. While downloading, if for some reason you are not able to download a presentation, the publisher may have deleted the file from their server. During download, if you can't get a presentation, the file might be deleted by the publisher.

E N D

Presentation Transcript


  1. PART III Growth Theory: The Economy in the Very Long Run Economic Growth I: Capital Accumulation and Population Growth Chapter 8 of Macroeconomics, 8thedition, by N. Gregory Mankiw ECO62UdayanRoy

  2. The Solow-Swan Model • This is a theory of macroeconomic dynamics • Using this theory, • you can predict where an economy will be tomorrow, the day after, and so on, if you know where it is today • you can predict the dynamic effects of changes in • the saving rate • the rate of population growth • and other factors

  3. Two productive resources and one produced good • There are two productive resources: • Capital, K • Labor, L • These two productive resources are used to produce one • final good, Y

  4. The Production Function • The production function is an equation that tells us how much of the final good is produced with specified amounts of capital and labor • Y = F(K, L) • Example: Y = 5K0.3L0.7

  5. Constant returns to scale • Y = F(K, L) = 5K0.3L0.7 • Note: • if you double both K and L, Y will also double • if you triple both K and L, Y will also triple • … and so on • This feature of the Y = 5K0.3L0.7 production function is called constant returns to scale The Solow-Swan model assumes that production functions obey constant returns to scale

  6. Constant returns to scale • Definition: The production function F(K, L) obeys constant returns to scale if and only if • for any positive number z (that is, z > 0) • F(zK, zL) = zF(K, L) • Example: Suppose F(K, L) = 5K0.3L0.7. • Then, for any z > 0, F(zK, zL) = 5(zK)0.3(zL)0.7 = 5z0.3K0.3z0.7L0.7 = 5z0.3 + 0.7K0.3L0.7 = z5K0.3L0.7 =zF(K, L) At this point, you should be able to do problem 1 (a) on page 232 of the textbook.

  7. Constant returns to scale • CRS requires F(zK, zL) = zF(K, L) for any z > 0 • Let z be 1/L. • Then, So, y = F(k, 1) . From now on, F(k, 1) will be denoted f(k), the per worker production function. k = K/Ldenotes per worker stock of capital y = Y/Ldenotes per worker output So, y= f(k) .

  8. Per worker production function: example At this point, you should be able to do problems 1 (b) and 3 (a) on pages 232 and 233 of the textbook. This is what a typical per worker production function looks like: concave

  9. The Cobb-Douglas Production Function • Y = F(K, L) = 5K0.3L0.7 • This production function is itself an instance of a more general production function called the Cobb-Douglas Production Function • Y = AKαL1 − α , • where A is any positive number (A > 0) and • α is any positive fraction (1 > α > 0)

  10. Per worker Cobb-Douglas production function • Y = AKαL1 − αimplies y = Akα = f(k) In problem 1 on page 232 of the textbook, you get Y = K1/2L1/2, which is the Cobb-Douglas production with A = 1 and α = ½. In problem 3 on page 233, you get Y = K0.3L0.7, which is the Cobb-Douglas production with A = 1 and α = 0.3.

  11. Per worker production function: graph

  12. Income, consumption, saving, investment • Output = income • The Solow-Swan model assumes that each individual saves a constant fraction, s, of his or her income • Therefore, saving per worker = sy = sf(k) • This saving becomes an addition to the existing capital stock • Consumption per worker is denoted c = y – sy = (1– s)y

  13. Income, consumption, saving, investment: graph

  14. Depreciation • But part of the existing capital stock wears out • This is called depreciation • The Solow-Swan model assumes that a constant fraction, δ, of the existing capital stock wears out in every period • That is, an individual who currently has k units of capital will lose δk units of capital though depreciation (or, wear and tear)

  15. Depreciation • Although 0 < δ < 1 is the fraction of existing capital that wears out every period, in some cases—as in problem 1 (c) on page 219 of the textbook—depreciation is expressed as a percentage. • In such cases, care must be taken to convert the percentage value to a fraction • For example, if depreciation is given as 5 percent, you need to set δ = 5/100 = 0.05

  16. Depreciation: graph

  17. dynamics

  18. Dynamics: what time is it? • We’ll attach a subscript to each variable to denote what date we’re talking about • For example, ktwill denote the economy’s per worker stock of capital on date tandkt+1 will denote the per worker stock of capital on date t + 1

  19. How does per worker capital change? • A worker haskt units of capital on date t • He or she adds syt units of capital through saving • and loses δkt units of capital through depreciation • So, each worker accumulates kt + syt−δktunits of capital on date t + 1 • Does this mean kt+1 = kt + syt−δkt? • Not quite!

  20. Population Growth • The Solow-Swan model assumes that each individual has n kids in each period • The kids become adult workers in the period immediately after they are born • and, like every other worker, have n kids of their own • and so on

  21. Population Growth • Let the growth rate of any variable x be denoted xg. It is calculated as follows: • Therefore, the growth rate of the number of workers, Lg, is:

  22. How does per worker capital change?

  23. Dynamics: algebra

  24. Dynamics: algebra Now we are ready for dynamics!

  25. Dynamics: algebra

  26. Dynamics: algebra At this point, you should be able to do problems 1 (d) and 3 (c) on pages 232 and 233 of the textbook. Please give them a try.

  27. Dynamics: algebra to graphs Although this is the basic Solow-Swan dynamic equation, a simple modification will help us analyze the theory graphically. Now we are ready for graphical analysis.

  28. Dynamics: algebra to graphs This version of the Solow-Swan equation will help us understand the model graphically.

  29. Dynamics: algebra to graphs This version of the Solow-Swan equation will help us understand the model graphically. 2. The economy shrinks if and only if per worker saving and investment [sf(kt)] is less than (δ + n)kt. 3. The economy is at a steady state if and only if per worker saving and investment [sf(kt)] is equal to (δ + n)kt. 1. The economy grows if and only if per worker saving and investment [sf(kt)] exceeds (δ + n)kt. 4. (δ + n)kt is called break-even investment

  30. Dynamics: graph

  31. Investment and break-even investment (δ + n)kt sf(kt) k1 k* Capital per worker, k Steady state

  32. Investment and depreciation (δ + n)kt sf(kt) k1 investment Break-even investment k1 k* Capital per worker, k Moving toward the steady state Steady state

  33. Investment and depreciation (δ + n)kt sf(kt) k1 k1 k* Capital per worker, k Moving toward the steady state k2 Steady state

  34. Investment and depreciation (δ + n)kt sf(kt) k2 investment Break-even investment k1 k* Capital per worker, k Moving toward the steady state k2 Steady state

  35. Investment and depreciation (δ + n)kt sf(kt) k2 k1 k* Capital per worker, k Moving toward the steady state k2 k3 Steady state

  36. Investment and depreciation (δ + n)kt sf(kt) k1 k* Capital per worker, k Moving toward the steady state As long as k < k*, investment will exceed break-even investment, and k will continue to grow toward k* k2 k3 Steady state

  37. Steady state

  38. The steady state: algebra • The economy eventually reaches the steady state • This happens when per worker saving and investment [sf(kt)] is equal to break-even investment [(δ + n)kt]. • For the Cobb-Douglas case, this condition is: At this point, you should be able to do problems 1 (c) and 3 (b) on pages 232 and 233 of the textbook. Please give them a try.

  39. Steady State and Transitional Dynamics: algebra

  40. Solow-swan predictions for the steady state

  41. There is no growth! • The Solow-Swan model predicts that • Every economy will end up at the steady-state; in the long run, the growth rate is zero! • That is, k = k* and y = f(k*) = y* • Growth is possible—temporarily!—only if the economy’s per worker stock of capital is less than the steady state per worker stock of capital (k < k*) • If k < k*, the smaller the value of k, the faster the growth of k and y

  42. There is no growth!

  43. From per worker to total • We have seen that per worker capital, k, is constant in the steady state • Now recall that k = K/L • and that L increases at the rate of n • Therefore,in the steady state, the total stock of capital, K, increases at the rate of n

  44. From per worker to total • We have seen that per worker income y = f(k) is constant in the steady state • Now recall that y = Y/L • and that L increases at the rate of n • Therefore,in the steady state, the total income, Y, must also increase at the rate of n • Similarly,although per worker saving and investment, sy, is constant in the steady state, total saving and investment, sY, increases at the rate n

  45. From per worker to per capita • Recall that L = amount of labor employed • Suppose P = amount of labor available • This is the labor force • But in the Solow-Swan model everybody is capable of work, even new-born children • So P can also be considered the population • Suppose u = fraction of population that is not engaged in production of the final good. • u is assumed constant • Then L = (1 – u)P or L/P= 1 – u

  46. Per worker to per capita

  47. Steady state: summary

  48. Solow-swan predictions for changes to the steady state

  49. A sudden fall in capital per worker • A sudden decrease in k could be caused by: • Earthquake or war that destroys capital but not people • Immigration • A decrease in u • What does the Solow-Swan model say will be the result of this?

  50. Investment and depreciation (δ + n)kt sf(kt) k1 k* Capital per worker, k A sudden fall in capital per worker At this point, you should be able to do problem 2 on pages 232 and 233 of the textbook. Please give it a try. 2. A gradual return to the steady state 1. A sudden decline

More Related