GG 541
Download
1 / 76

gg 541 - PowerPoint PPT Presentation


  • 261 Views
  • Uploaded on

GG 541. Professor T. R. Lakshmanan. September 23, 2008. Key Components of CBA ◊ User benefits (times, fares, vehicle operating costs, safety etc.) ◊ Investment costs ◊ Operator costs and revenues ◊ Impacts on government - taxation subsidies

loader
I am the owner, or an agent authorized to act on behalf of the owner, of the copyrighted work described.
capcha
Download Presentation

PowerPoint Slideshow about 'gg 541' - jaden


An Image/Link below is provided (as is) to download presentation

Download Policy: Content on the Website is provided to you AS IS for your information and personal use and may not be sold / licensed / shared on other websites without getting consent from its author.While downloading, if for some reason you are not able to download a presentation, the publisher may have deleted the file from their server.


- - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - E N D - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - -
Presentation Transcript
Slide1 l.jpg

GG 541

Professor T. R. Lakshmanan

September 23, 2008


Slide2 l.jpg

Key Components of CBA

◊ User benefits (times, fares, vehicle operating costs,

safety etc.)

◊ Investment costs

◊ Operator costs and revenues

◊ Impacts on government - taxation subsidies

◊ Externalities (environmental, congestion)


Slide3 l.jpg

User Benefit Estimation

Three concepts underlying the definition of user benefit:

◊ Willingness to Pay (WTP)

◊ Consumer Surplus (CS)

◊ Generalized Cost (GC)


Slide4 l.jpg

WTP is the maximum amount of money an individual

is willing to pay for the change in his/her circumstances,

e.g to make a trip from i to j using mode m.

If the price (p) of the trip is less than or equal to WPT, the

individual is assumed to make the trip.

If P is > WTP, the traveler will find an alternative, which

may be not the travel at all.


Slide5 l.jpg

WTP is grounded in the acceptance of Consumer Sovereignty, so that it does not apply to goods subject to per se social or moral judgment.

WTP can still be applied to cases of externalities (negative spill overs).

However, if a community places extra value on social interactions promoted by public transit, that value will not be captured by the sum of individual willingness to pay for transit trips (only if one could also separately measure and include individual WTP for a better social milieu likely to result for more social interactions)


Slide6 l.jpg

Continued… so that it does not apply to goods subject to

Note - different individuals have different levels of

WTP for the same ijm trip.

One can construct the demand function for ijm trips,

linking the price to number of trips demanded - a downward sloping demand curve.


Slide7 l.jpg

CBA is a comparative tool, involving a comparison of so that it does not apply to goods subject to

alternative states of the world.

A do-something scenario

- Where a link or facility is included in the transport network.

these will be a separate do-something scenario for each

alternative version of the project.

A realistic do-minimum scenario

- With the project not implemented. The do-minimum

scenario will include a realistic level of maintenance and a

minimum set of minor improvements to avoid the

transport deterioration.


Slide8 l.jpg

The Do-Minimum Scenario so that it does not apply to goods subject to


Slide9 l.jpg

DD, the demand function represents the number of trips so that it does not apply to goods subject to

that would be made at different levels of generalized costs -

a few trips with large economic benefit made at high costs,

and less beneficial trips at lower costs.

The intersection of the supply function s yields

the number of trips made. CS, consumer surplus is a

measure of the excess of willingness to pay over the

generalized cost of the trip - the area CS under the

demand curve and above a horizontal line indicating the

current price (GCo).


Slide10 l.jpg

Operationalizing the concept in transport poses some so that it does not apply to goods subject to

problems. For most goods, the vertical axis indicates

price .

In the case of transport, prices and money costs are

not only one part of the composite. Cost of transit, which

in principle incorporates travel times, access times to

public transport, discomfort, perceived safety risk and

others. Hence price is replaced by Generalized

Cost (GC).


Slide11 l.jpg

GC represents the money equivalent of the overall so that it does not apply to goods subject to

cost and inconvenience to the transport user engaged

in travel between origin (i) and destination (j) by a

particular mode (m). While in principle, it includes all

aspects of ‘quality’ factors, in practice GC is limited to

three elements.

GCC ijm = time cost ijm + user charges ijm + VOC ijm

Value of time costs vary among individuals and even for

the same individual depending upon the trip purpose and

their factors.


Slide13 l.jpg

The User Benefit so that it does not apply to goods subject to

1

0

  • CSijm (=CSijm – CSijm) is estimated by the rule of a half

  • (ROH) on assumption that the demand curve between

  • (Q1GC0) and (Q1GC1) is linear approximately

  • ∆CS= 1/2 (GCo - GC1)(Q1 - Q)

  • This procedure repeated for transport users as well

  • as for freight users.

1


Slide14 l.jpg

Components of GC will vary by mode so that it does not apply to goods subject to

* Public Transport users - fare plus costs of time of

travel

* Car users - costs of time, toll charges, fuel costs plus

VOCs

Differences in repeated user benefits for users of different modes (e.g. Public transport users do not have VOC benefits)


Slide15 l.jpg

Producer Surplus so that it does not apply to goods subject to

PS - TR - TC

where TR is total revenue

and TC is total costs

∆PS = ∆ TR - ∆ TC


Slide17 l.jpg

In the case of diagram (a) there is a rail journey time so that it does not apply to goods subject to

improvement, but marginal costs and fares (which

are above marginal costs) stay constant [benefits]

The change in the producer surplus ( DPS)

is “net revenue gain”


Slide18 l.jpg

continued so that it does not apply to goods subject to …

Figure 3a is the case in which the benefits are fully passed

through to the travelers

Figure 3b – there is complete “pricing up” by the railway

operators. Thus the size of the revenue and user benefits

effects (as well as their distribution) depends upon

pricing policy.


Slide19 l.jpg

Operating Costs so that it does not apply to goods subject to

Costs of infrastructure operation (e.g. signaling/traffic control)

 Maintenance costs (cleaning, minor repairs, winter services)

 Costs of renewals (road/rail reconstruction)

 Changes in VOCs of Public Transport Services


Slide20 l.jpg

Investment Costs so that it does not apply to goods subject to

Some adjustments to Investment Costs include:

Mitigation Measures (EIS, etc.)

Disruption (effect of disruptions on traffic revenues and on

service quality)

Consistent Account

(Market prices or factor costs basis)


Slide21 l.jpg

Travel Time Savings so that it does not apply to goods subject to

  • Dominant item of benefits, especially for air travel,

  • urban community and surface freight shipping

  • - Big time savings occur when there is

  • A new high speed rail service

  • A new highway through previously underdeveloped land

  • Congestion relief from expanding capacity

  • Improved rail switching facilities

  • Upgrade a line haul facility to permit higher speeds


Slide22 l.jpg

An extensive literature based on demand models so that it does not apply to goods subject to

suggests that people and firms make reasonably predictable trade-offs between travel time and other factors when they make travel choices. From these studies, attempts to estimate WTP for travel time savings, a quantity known as the ‘Value of Time’ (VOT).


Slide23 l.jpg

VOT Varies Across so that it does not apply to goods subject to

- population subgroups and also on individual

circumstances

e.g. people WTP more on average

to avoid time walking to a bus stop or waiting there

than they are willing to pay to avoid the same amount of

time riding on the bus.

Also willing to pay more to avoid driving in congested

conditions.


Slide24 l.jpg

These variations not surprising as time is not fungible: so that it does not apply to goods subject to

time saved in one circumstance cannot be automatically

used in another – examples:

These variations must be considered:

Predicting travel time savings often complicated by

offsetting behavioral shifts as a result of unpriced

congestion.

The case of latentdemand

Amount of travel time savings overstated


Slide25 l.jpg

The Case of Land Use Distortions so that it does not apply to goods subject to

Failure to price highway congestion leads to the city

being inefficiently decentralized. New highways

exacerbate this effect by creating housing locations

which create longer trips and more traffic. So

congestion will be reduced by a project less than

predicted.


Slide26 l.jpg

In estimating VOT, distinction is made between: so that it does not apply to goods subject to

1. travel in working time

2. travel in non-working time (e.g. shopping,

commuting, education, personal business,

leisure)

3. freight travel time


Slide27 l.jpg

Working time value is easy to analyze because there is a market (labor market) where working time is valued

Two approaches

Adapt the gross wage rate (wage plus employee -

related overheads) as a measure of the marginal

product of labor

minutes of travel time savings

in working time

VOT = gross wage/min X


Slide28 l.jpg

Second approach by Hensher qualifies the previous approach in two ways:

1) The ability to work while traveling (varies by mode)

The ability to use productively any travel time saved also varies, depending upon the extent to which work tasks are divisible and flexible.


Slide29 l.jpg

Non-working Time Savings Value in two ways:

No market exists

A WTP value based on market research

Both revealed preference (RP) and stated preference (SP methods used for VOT in different situations - including route choice, mode choice etc.


Slide30 l.jpg

Value of Non-working Time Varies with Disposable Income in two ways:

  • - Disposable income

  • - Employment status

  • Type of activity (walk and wait higher than in

  • vehicle time, congestion) and with mode (comfort,

  • privacy)

  • Journey purpose and journey lengths

  • Pragmatic use of standard values


Slide31 l.jpg

Freight Travel Time Savings in two ways:

  •  Most important savings in drivers time

  • Not only VOC savings but those resulting from trip

  • rescheduling which leads to total labor cost reduction

  •  Also the ability to adapt more efficient logistics - the

  • process and service innovations and the resulting

  • productivity in access.


Slide32 l.jpg

Appraisal Values for Travel Time Savings in two ways:

- an example: UK Official Values

Notes: (a) all values have been converted to 1999 US$, (b) Other goods vehicles include

heavy goods vehicles. c) PSVs are public service vehicles, principally buses. (d)Walking,

waiting and, cycling in non-working time are given double this value.


Slide33 l.jpg

CBA with Externalities in two ways:

Transport provision often leads to a variety of negative or positive external effects (e.g. Air pollution, congestion, accidents and fatalities and airport noises are negative externalities. External economies of agglomeration is an example of positive externalities.


Slide34 l.jpg

CBA with Externalities in two ways:

Here the private cost of travel is increased by an

external cost e.


Slide35 l.jpg

Because of the upward sloping nature of the in two ways:

s + e functions, the estimated benefit (a social benefit here) will

be lower than the user benefit (in the simple user benefit case)

by the amount E, which represents the extra external cost

imposed by the increase in trips. If one wants to reduce

pollution, a positive adjustment is needed.

To implement this adjustment, it must be possible to

calculate the net change in external cost in monetary terms and

subtract it from the calculated user benefits.


Slide36 l.jpg

Congestion Effects in two ways:


Slide37 l.jpg

Congestion is a reciprocal externality. When the in two ways:

traffic exceeds design capacity, all vehicles experience

congestion. As congestion increases, travel time is

an increasing function of the number of users of the

transport link. As a consequence, the horizontal supply

function is to be replaced by an upward sloping segment.

Infrastructure improvement leads to an increase in design

capacity, thus shifting the upward sloping segment to the

right as in previous figure.


Slide38 l.jpg

continued in two ways:…

Calculation of congestion costs must not be on a link basis but on a transport network basis.

Please note that trips induced by the transport

improvement may negate much of the benefit that might otherwise have accrued to freight users.


Slide39 l.jpg

Value of Safety Impacts in two ways:

Some of the safety projects are market driven, while some safety proposals are government mandated.

Changes in the risk of injuries, fatal or otherwise can be

assessed based on WTP.

Decisions are made implicitly placing values on additional

risks incurred.

A reliable method to value risk of death appears to be

comparing wages for jobs that are similar in all respects

except occupational risk.


Slide40 l.jpg

Review of such studies suggest that on average people in affluent industrialized countries are willing to pay (early 1990s) $3 - $7 for each reduction of one in a million in the risk of death.

Take $5, and a million people, their aggregate WTP for saving one life is $5 million.

- “value of life” (VOL) 5 million


Slide41 l.jpg

Most government agencies use a value of VOL of much affluent industrialized countries are willing to pay (early 1990s) $3 - $7 for each reduction of one in a million in the risk of death.

less than $5 million.

Canada $1.4 million (Canadian) (1991).

[Even this amount is higher than those the average person’s

personal wealth or the discounted sum of future earnings]

No one is paying to avoid a sure death; rather people are paying to lower the probabilities slightly.


Slide42 l.jpg

Risk of serious injuries or illnesses evaluated in a similar affluent industrialized countries are willing to pay (early 1990s) $3 - $7 for each reduction of one in a million in the risk of death.

fashion.

WTP to reduce the risk of typical serious (but non fatal) traffic injury is 10% of WTP (for traffic fatality).

Note that the government borne costs of medical treatment must be added.


Slide43 l.jpg

Some Countries Public Official Values for affluent industrialized countries are willing to pay (early 1990s) $3 - $7 for each reduction of one in a million in the risk of death.

CBA Purposes


Slide45 l.jpg

Environmental Impacts of Transport affluent industrialized countries are willing to pay (early 1990s) $3 - $7 for each reduction of one in a million in the risk of death.

The challenge for CBA is to find ways to bring these impacts (air pollution, noise, or regional long run problems such as acid rain and global warming) into the CBA framework in a consistent way, given the greater uncertainty associated with environmental problems.

Noise: Hedonic analysis of rental property to get the

impact of noise.


Slide46 l.jpg

Values generated by the approach are typically of the order affluent industrialized countries are willing to pay (early 1990s) $3 - $7 for each reduction of one in a million in the risk of death.

of 30 Euros/person per dB per annum in year 2000 prices

(Grant-Muller).

This value adjusted to other countries using PPP exchange

rates


Slide47 l.jpg

Particulates most Significant Air Pollutant affluent industrialized countries are willing to pay (early 1990s) $3 - $7 for each reduction of one in a million in the risk of death.

Damage costs much higher /unit mass of pollutant emitted

in urban (US non urban areas) - 50 times as much

in London vs. rural areas.

46-740 Euros/kgm.

High level of uncertainty - sensitivity testing necessary.


Slide48 l.jpg

The CBA Process affluent industrialized countries are willing to pay (early 1990s) $3 - $7 for each reduction of one in a million in the risk of death.


Slide49 l.jpg

CBA Process affluent industrialized countries are willing to pay (early 1990s) $3 - $7 for each reduction of one in a million in the risk of death.

Inputs - modeling & forecasting all inputs (time, cost and

time). Estimates of investment costs, safety and

environmental impacts.

Consistent Benefit Estimation - Use ROH for user benefits and

simple do-minimum vs. do-something comparison for other

cost and benefit items initially for one or two years.

Interpolation and Extrapolation - using growth rates for

quantities and unit values, to arrive at cost and benefit

streams over the entire appraisal period.


Slide50 l.jpg

continued….. affluent industrialized countries are willing to pay (early 1990s) $3 - $7 for each reduction of one in a million in the risk of death.

Discounting - Discount future costs and benefits in line

with public sector conventions on discount rates.

Summary Measures - over all measure in CBA terms.


Slide51 l.jpg

Discounting the Future affluent industrialized countries are willing to pay (early 1990s) $3 - $7 for each reduction of one in a million in the risk of death.

Valuing future benefits less because of

* People’s impatience or

* The productive possibilities for investing their money

Discount rate related to the interest rate on financial assets.


Slide52 l.jpg

continued affluent industrialized countries are willing to pay (early 1990s) $3 - $7 for each reduction of one in a million in the risk of death.…

Departures from perfectly competitive markets result in

wedges between interest rates faced by different economic

factors.

Take a risk-free government bond with real after-tax-

interest rate rc (usually 4%).

Investment earns a real net social rate of return

(marginal product of capital) ri (9.6% in 1989).

How about a weighted average of rc and ri.

In US, OMB (Office of Management & Budget) uses since

1993, a social discount rate of 7% (Australia 7%, Canada 10%).


Slide53 l.jpg

Main summary measure of net social benefit is the Net affluent industrialized countries are willing to pay (early 1990s) $3 - $7 for each reduction of one in a million in the risk of death.

Present Value (NPV)

t=n

Bt-Ct-Kt

NPV = ∑

l-r

t=0

Where Bt are the benefits in year t

Cb the recurring costs in year t

kt the investment costs in year t

r the social discount rate

[reflecting the social opportunity cost of capital]

n number of years in the appraisal period


Slide54 l.jpg

Decision Rules affluent industrialized countries are willing to pay (early 1990s) $3 - $7 for each reduction of one in a million in the risk of death.

- Accept all projects with a positive NPV

- Accept the highest project option with the

highest NPV, when there are mutually

exclusive alternatives


Slide55 l.jpg

Under budget constraints use B/C ratio. affluent industrialized countries are willing to pay (early 1990s) $3 - $7 for each reduction of one in a million in the risk of death.

Kt

t=n

Bt-Ct

t=n

BCR=

(l+r)t

(l+r)t

t=0

t=0

Accept projects based on a marginally acceptable B/C ratio.


Slide56 l.jpg

Presentation format of CBA analysis affluent industrialized countries are willing to pay (early 1990s) $3 - $7 for each reduction of one in a million in the risk of death.


Slide58 l.jpg

The previous table shows the aggregate social costs and benefits as well as the benefits accruing to

different incidence groups - identifying gainers and losers.

Discuss the case.


Slide59 l.jpg

Issues in CBA benefits as well as the benefits accruing to

Projections of Capital Costs & Travel Demand

Projected estimates are required of:

 up front capital costs

 the future operating costs

 the future demand for travel on the facility


Slide60 l.jpg

Record on these projections very choppy. benefits as well as the benefits accruing to

In affluent countries record is not very encouraging.

- For ten rail transit systems recently built in the US.

Capital costs underestimated (up to 1/3) in nine cases

(Don Pickrell); in eight cases ridership was

overestimated (by a factor of 3).

- Even for toll highways (bond financed) 10 out of 14 had

less toll revenues well below projections.

- Similar experience for 7 large Danish highway bridges.


Slide61 l.jpg

continued benefits as well as the benefits accruing to….

Case of toll road near Vancouver, BC. Ex post CBA

showed that ex ante CBA drastically underestimated both

actual construction costs and actual traffic - offsetting

errors but still humbling.

Is there a strategic bias in these ex ante CBAs?


Slide62 l.jpg

The Case of CBA in LDCs - quite different benefits as well as the benefits accruing to

The World Bank experience in LDCs ($50 billion in transport

projects).

Estimated Returns from World Bank Projects


Slide63 l.jpg

Extensions of CBA benefits as well as the benefits accruing to

 Logistics Cost Effects

 Facilities Consolidation

 Other Location Effects


Slide64 l.jpg

Total Logistics Costs benefits as well as the benefits accruing to

Total Logistics Costs (TLC) = PC + C + TC

Where PC = Procurement Costs

C = Carrying Costs

TC= Transport costs

PC and TC (Unit Costs) will be lower , the larger the shipment

C, which includes storage cots, interest on inventory and

Insurance, will be proportional to shipment size


Slide65 l.jpg

Total Logistics Costs benefits as well as the benefits accruing to

P+T and C are grouped against the average shipment

size B, optimal B is where TLC (T+P+C) is a minimum.

Given the tradeoff between TP and C. Logistical systems

such as Just-in-time (JIT) ----***


Slide66 l.jpg

Measures of Travel Time Reduction Impacts on Costs benefits as well as the benefits accruing to

(Hickling, Lewis, Brod, 1995)


Slide67 l.jpg

Elasticity of logistics costs e benefits as well as the benefits accruing tol with respect to travel

time reduction.

Compare the high el for a high value added industry

compared to retail food.

[caution: result of a limited survey]


Slide68 l.jpg

Provision of Infrastructure & Industry Levels benefits as well as the benefits accruing to

Shirly and Winston (2001) using the Census Bureau’s

Logitational Research Database find support for the

view that lower transportation costs and higher

reliability allow firms to maintain

lower inventories.


Slide69 l.jpg

Facility Consolidation benefits as well as the benefits accruing to

Reduced freight costs allow a multifacility firm to concentrate its production and distribution facility locations in fewer locations to take advantage of scale economies.

Substantial savings in logistical costs

Case study of a firm in medical surgical products

with $1.8 billion sales in 1990.


Slide70 l.jpg

Logistics Cost Savings due to Facilities Consolidation, Medical and Surgical Products Case Study

Hickling (1995)


Slide71 l.jpg

Location Effects Medical and Surgical Products Case Study

Transport improvements contribute to productivity

growth through mechanisms that involve the

location choice of the firm.

The Case of Agglomeration Economies

several types:

* Urbanization Economies

(scale economies in the provision of public infrastructure

in concentrated areas of public demand)


Slide72 l.jpg

continued Medical and Surgical Products Case Study….

* Juxtaposition Economies

(reduction in the cost of transferring intermediate

goods among diverse firms linked together in the

production chain)

* Localized Economies

(spillovers of knowledge and labor skills that occur

when firms in the same industry cluster together)

Significant productivity benefits to economic agglomeration promoted by lowered transport costs.


Slide73 l.jpg

Interstate System and the “greenfield” production sites Medical and Surgical Products Case Study

in peripheral areas.

Transportation promotes productivity both ways:

through clustering and also by spreading at the

urban periphery.

- Different firms need different locations

- The product life-cycle model


Slide74 l.jpg

Benefits of agglomeration offset at some point by Medical and Surgical Products Case Study

congestion.

A new project often reduces the congestion.


Slide75 l.jpg

Transport and Value Added Medical and Surgical Products Case Study

Adding value to the output of either the freight using firms or the transportation service provider.

The case of fresh fish with transport improvements.

It is possible to get fish from Maine to St. Louis in less than a day after catch. Fish can be produced only in a few places & has a scarcity value elsewhere. Now the fish producing firm expands its market, and reaches markets where its output has a higher value than its local market.


ad