Introductory comment
This presentation is the property of its rightful owner.
Sponsored Links
1 / 57

Introductory Comment PowerPoint PPT Presentation


  • 36 Views
  • Uploaded on
  • Presentation posted in: General

Introductory Comment. Our argument is very simple. It may not surprise anyone in this audience. But it is a big departure from the standard view in economics. We claim that The methodological arguments against explaining economic change by changes in preferences are no longer convincing.

Download Presentation

Introductory Comment

An Image/Link below is provided (as is) to download presentation

Download Policy: Content on the Website is provided to you AS IS for your information and personal use and may not be sold / licensed / shared on other websites without getting consent from its author.While downloading, if for some reason you are not able to download a presentation, the publisher may have deleted the file from their server.


- - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - E N D - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - -

Presentation Transcript


Introductory comment

Introductory Comment

Our argument is very simple. It may not surprise anyone in this audience. But it is a big departure from the standard view in economics.

We claim that

  • The methodological arguments against explaining economic change by changes in preferences are no longer convincing.

  • We ultimately need to know the extent to which institutions and historical events shape preferences.


Tastes castes and culture the influence of society on preferences

Tastes, Castes, and Culture:The Influence of Society on Preferences

Ernst Fehr

Department of Economics

Laboratory for Social and Neural Systems Research

University of Zurich

Karla Hoff

World Bank

Paris School of Economics

November 25, 2011


Outline of presentation

Outline of presentation

I. The “stable preferences assumption“

  • Sociologists‘ view

  • Economists‘ view

    II. How sound is the economists‘ traditional view?

  • Anchoring and framing effects on preferences

    III. Preference-based explanations may help explain outstanding puzzles

    • Persistent changes in preferences from social influences


Part i are preferences stable or are they shaped by society a sociologist s view

Part I.Are preferences stable or are they shaped by “society“?A sociologist‘s view

“The assumption that society shapes individuals‘ preferences clearly concerns one of the core pillars of sociology but it is not easy to suggest any literature to you. It is almost too fundamental for that – like asking economists to suggest some tests on the importance of choice. Almost all sociologists take it as obvious that individuals‘ preferences are formed by society and that society, so to speak, exists within persons.“ Peter Hedstrom, Oxford, personal communication


Are preferences stable or are they shaped by society a view from economics

Are preferences stable or are they shaped by “society“?A view from economics

  • De Gustibus non est disputandum (Stigler & Becker, 1977)

    • “... tastes neither change capriciously nor differ importantly between people. On this interpretation one does not argue about tastes for the same reason that one does not argue over the Rocky Mountains – both are there, will be there next year, too, and are the same to all men.“

  • Not just stable preferences, but also no heterogeneity


Stigler becker cont d

Stigler & Becker cont‘d

  • Assuming unstable and heterogeneous preferences leads to intellectual laziness

    • “We also claim that no significant behavior has been illuminated by assumptions of differences in tastes. Instead, they, along with assumptions of unstable tastes have been a convenient crutch to lean on when the analysis has bogged down. They give the appearance of considered judgment, yet really have only been ad hoc arguments that disguise analytical failures“


Not all economists subscribe to this extreme view but

Not all economists subscribe to this extreme view but ...

  • Almost all economic research examines the changes in individual behavior and aggregate outcomes that follow from changes in constraints

    • Tax, cost, price and information changes

    • Changes in property rights & the contractual environment

  • Implicit assumption

    • Strong preference stability: changes in constraints (“the environment“) leave preferences unaffected

    • Weak preference stability: for the problem under consideration preferences are more stable than constraints


Remarks on the assumption of preference stability

Remarks on the assumption of preference stability

  • Important to recognize

    • It is NOT a fact that changes in the environment leave preferences unaffected

    • It is merely a useful assumption that took on the nature of a social convention

    • It is considered bad practice to invoke changes in preferences as explanations

  • “One can explain everything if one invokes changes in preferences as an explanation“

  • “It is too easy to explain changes in behavior by changes in preferences“


But recent progress in game theory creates a new problem

...But recent progress in game theory creates a new problem

  • A clever contract theorist can say:

  • “Give me a real world contract and I will find an extensive form game that rationalizes this contract as an equilibrium of the game“


John sutton

John Sutton

  • The elaboration of multi-stage games allowed a tremendous flexibility in modelling.


Sutton continued

Paradoxically, it is the very success of these game theoretic models in providing a rich menu of candidate “explanations,“ which leaves them open to a quite fundamental line of criticism

This richness of possible formulations leads to an often embarrassingly wide range of outcomes supportable as equilibria within some “reasonable“ specification

In explaining everything, have we explained nothing? What do these models exclude?

Sutton, continued


Our view

Our View

  • The methodological arguments against invoking preference changes are not very convincing

  • The arguments rest on conventions, social norms and (unproven) beliefs about the empirical validity of the assumption that one can neglect changes in preferences for the problem at hand

  • Deep down, most of us believe that preferences are shaped by teaching, role models, the behaviors we observe around us and our social interactions with other people

    • Educating one‘s children is not just about skill formation – it‘s also about teaching the “right“ preferences


However

However

  • It is a huge empirical challenge to prove a causal impact of “society“ on preferences

  • This has kept second-best conventions in economics alive

    • but ultimately we want to know the extent to which preferences are shaped by society

  • We next turn to psychological mechanisms that make preferences susceptible to social influences


Part ii framing effects on visual perception

Part IIFraming effects on visual perception

  • People often assume that what they see with their own eyes is a correct representation of reality

  • But in fact, our perception of objects is shaped by context.


Introductory comment

  • Müller-Lyer illusion


Framing effects on preferences

Framing effects on preferences

Frames in economics are observables that:

  • Are irrelevant in the rational assessment of the alternatives,

  • But nonetheless affect behavior--

    • Triggering a particular way of thinking about a choice

    • Determining what details of a set of choices are salient, or

    • Evoking a self-concept, norm, or world view


Example from coherent arbitrariness ariely loewenstien and prelec 2003

Example from “Coherent Arbitrariness“Ariely, Loewenstien, and Prelec (2003)

  • The study elicits willingness to pay for various goods

  • For each item, subjects are asked whether they are willing to pay more or less than a certain price

  • The price is based on the last two digits of their Social Security number:

  • After this anchoring question, the experiment elicits the willingness to pay

$19

19


Average willingness to pay sorted by participants social security number

Average willingness-to-pay sorted by participants’ Social Security number

range of the last two digits

$40

of SS number 00-39

range of the last two digits

of SS number 40-99

$30

$20

$10

0

Trackball

Keyboard

Cote du

Hermitage

Design book

Belgian

Rhone

chocolates


Introductory comment

  • The power of arbitrary numbers as anchors is replicated even where the individual has just experienced the pleasure or pain of an object

  • So no rationalization in terms of information problems is possible

Which suggests

To the extent that social institutions prime individuals’

identities and act as anchoring & framing devices,

they also shape preferences.


Example from fairness perceptions and reservation wages falk fehr zehnder 2007

Example from “Fairness perceptions and reservation wages” Falk-Fehr-Zehnder (2007)

  • This study elicits reservation wage before the introduction of a minimum wage and after abolishing the minimum wage

    • Minimum wages cause increases in reservation wages even after they have been abolished!

    • No rationalization in terms of different constraints possible


Example from making up people hoff and pandey 2006 2011

Example from “Making Up People” Hoff and Pandey (2006, 2011)

  • Boys from high castes and from the traditionally “untouchable” castes asked to solve mazes under incentives

  • Boys are randomly assigned to one of three groups that vary the salience of caste:

    • Caste identity is not made public in the maze-solving session

    • It is made public in a session of 3 high- and 3 low-caste boys

    • It is made public in a session of 6 high-caste boys (or 6 low-caste boys). Thus subjects find themselves segregated by caste status—an event that would be extremely unlikely to occur by pure chance


Segregation is a strong cue to the caste system

Segregation is a strong cue to the caste system

  • The caste system still more or less prevails in villages

  • The caste system mandates segregation of high from low castes

    • In 1 out of 4 primary schools in rural India, Dalit children are forced by their teachers or by convention to sit apart from non-Dalits

    • As many as 40% of schools practice untouchability while serving mid-day meals, making Dalit children sit in a separate row while eating.

      --Shah et al.’s survey of 565 villages across 11 states of India in 2001-02


Introductory comment

Cars for transporting the participants to form sessions of boys from different villages

Hardoi District, Uttar Pradesh


Introductory comment

Set-up of experiment room

If caste is announced, that is done as soon as the participants are seated. Then the experimenter explains how to solve a maze and what a child will earn from maze-solving. The children solve mazes in two 15-min. rounds.


Introductory comment

To the extent possible participants in a session are drawn from six different cars (villages)

Participants as they are about to be taken home


Average output of high caste subjects

Average output of high-caste subjects

Identity not revealed

Identity revealed in a mixed group

Identity revealed in a segregated group

7

6

5

4

3

2

1

0

Round 1

Round 2


Comments on results for high caste

Comments on results for high caste

  • In this experiment, individual output depends only on the individual’s preferences and ability

  • There is no plausible reason why the ability of the high-caste subjects should be impaired by placing them in sessions of only high-caste boys

  • In fact, the evidence on the next slide suggests that priming caste increases the high caste’s ability to perform. The effect for the low caste is the reverse. These two effects are consistent with “stereotype susceptibility” (Steele-Aronson 1995).


Probability of failing to learn how to solve a maze

Probability of failing to learn how to solve a maze

0.12

0.1

Identity not revealed

0.08

0.06

Identity revealed

0.04

0.02

0

High caste

Low caste


Why do high caste subjects expend less effort in the segregated sessions

Why do high-caste subjects expend less effort in the segregated sessions?

  • Making caste highly salient may activate a mental frame in which a high-caste person has:

    • less need to achieve, so

    • less need to work hard.

  • Why? We have learned from the society in which we live a variety of roles

  • Segregating by caste may act as a “frame switch”

    Swidler (1986) & DiMaggio (1997)


More evidence of multiple preference orderings frame switches

More evidence of “multiple preference orderings” & “frame switches”

  • Priming Asian identity of Asian-Americans leads them to be:

    • more cooperative,

    • less individualistic, &

    • more patient

  • Priming a “family-oriented” identity triggers values related to family obligations

  • Priming an “occupation-oriented” identity triggers values related to obligations to one’s firm

    • LeBoeuf et al. 2010 , Benjamin et al. 2010


Introductory comment

The frame primes the duck


Introductory comment

The frame primes the rabbit


Part iii preference based explanations may help explain outstanding puzzles

Part III Preference-based explanations may help explain outstanding puzzles

  • The rest of this talk is more speculative


Hypothesis 1

Hypothesis 1

  • An individual’s position in an extreme social hierarchy affects:

    • his agency &/or

    • his in-group affiliation, & thus

    • his willingness to punish violations of a cooperation norm that hurt in-group members


Caste and punishment hoff kshetramade fehr 2011

“Caste and Punishment”(Hoff-Kshetramade-Fehr 2011)

  • We examined the impact of caste status on punishment while controlling for in-group/out-group, wealth, and education effects


Set up

Set-up

  • Groups of 3 members interact: player A, B, and C

  • Each lives in a different and distant village in north India

  • A and B play a trust game

  • C is an uninvolved third party who can punish B

    • For every 2 rupee coin that C spends, B loses 10 rupees


Trust game with third party punishment

Trust game with third-party punishment

C chooses punishment for cooperation

Sends back half to A

B

Keeps all the money

Sends to B

C chooses punishment for defection

Money triples

A

Doesn’t send


Result

Result

  • High-caste men are more willing than low-caste men to punish norm violations that hurt a member of their “in-group” (subcaste)

    So low caste members seem to care less for ”their“ in-group members

  • Can this be explained by differences in wealth?


Do richer individuals punish more land ownership

Do richer individuals punish more?(land ownership)


Do richer individuals punish more house ownership

Do richer individuals punish more?(house ownership)


Introductory comment

  • Across the two caste status groups, subjects face identical constraints in our game

  • The caste difference in punishing cannot be explained in terms of differences:

    • In payoffs in the game

    • In education

    • In wealth

  • The difference is interesting because

    • Fehr et al. (1997) indicates that altruistic sanctioning is a powerful means of enforcing contracts.


Vicious circle of caste

Vicious circle of caste?

  • If the lower willingness to punish contract violations is also associated with a lower propensity to punish free-riders in collective action

  • Then the low castes would be less able to discipline free-riders and thus to organize collective action, which could contribute to

    • Persistence of the caste system


Hypothesis 2

Hypothesis 2

Culture shapes the demand for social insurance


Attitudes toward government redistribution vary across countries

Attitudes toward government redistribution vary across countries

Survey question: Should government reduce income differences?

Eugster et al. 2011


German and latin language regions in switzerland

“German” and “Latin” language regions in Switzerland


Votes in swiss referenda on social security

Votes in Swiss Referenda on Social Security

German-speaking |Latin language speaking German-speaking |Latin language speaking German-speaking |Latin language speaking

Year the vote was held is in parentheses. Communities are collected in bins by their distance to the language border, in 5km intervals. Dots show the per cent Yes-votes of all validly cast votes, per 5 km bin of communities. Negative distances correspond to majority German-speaking communities; positive distances correspond to major French-, Italian, or Romansh-speaking communities. The vertical line indicates the language border. Also shown is a LOWESS fit to the bin-level shares, a locally weighted regression using 80% of the data to smooth each point.

Eugster et al. 2011


Establishing causality

Establishing causality

  • In a within-canton regression discontinuity design,

    • Using data from all referenda on social insurance from 1980-2009 in Switzerland,

    • & controlling for a wide set of factors,

    • The German group still has a much lower demand than the “Latin“ group for social insurance

      Cultural differences, not differences in constraints, cause the differences

      Eugster et al. 2011


Conclusion

Conclusion

  • McCloskey (1998) imagines a heckler defending the standard economic paradigm with fixed preferences:

    “Give me a break: I’m not in the business of explaining all behaviour. I propose merely to explain some portion, and in many cases a large portion.”

    • This would be a plausible objection if changes in constraints (“the environment“) left preferences unaffected, or if, for the problem under consideration, preferences were more stable than constraints


Introductory comment

  • But evidence suggests that changes in constraints can change preferences


Introductory comment

Examples

Change in preferences

Change in a constraint

Why?

Change in minimum wage

Change in reservation wage

Entitlement effect

Falk, Fehr,

Zehnder 2006

Cues to the caste order lower the willingness of the high caste to expend effort (a framing effect)

Possibly a decline in the need to achieve

Hoff-Pandey

2006, 2011

Caste

One’s position at the top or bottom of the caste order shapes the willingness to punish norm violations

Effect on agency

&/or

in-group affiliation

Hoff,

Kshetramade,

Fehr 2011

Lindbeck-

Nyberg 2006

Expansion of the

welfare state

The work ethic of the next generation is reduced

Rational adaptationof parentingstrategies


Take away message institutions have broader implications than economists have generally recognized

Take-away message Institutions have broader implications than economists have generally recognized

Institutions(“rules of the game”)

Constraints & beliefs

&

Preferences by

  • activating a particular self-concept or world-view (one of many that are held)

  • shaping a new self-concept or world-view

  • creating systems of meaning

Influence

Influence


Introductory comment

  • Investigating the causal influences on preferences remains a huge challenge,

  • But is likely to shed light on changes central to economic change


Introductory comment

  • One further note on framing effects on visual perception

  • According to Segall et al. (1966),

  • The Müller-Lyer illusion is completely absent in some undeveloped societies

  • In the West, the illusion is strongest. Why?

  • Exposure to ‘carpentered corners’ of modern environments mayhave led to certain visual habits that perpetuate this illusion.

  • “If even a process as apparently basic as visual perception can

  • show substantial variation across populations, …what kind of

  • psychological processes can we be sure will not vary?”

  • Henrich et al. (2010)


Introductory comment

Thank you for your attention


Post talk discussion elicitation effects on preferences

Post-talk discussion: “Elicitation effects” on preferences

An additional effect of institutions on preferences/behavior is through default options, e.g. in retirement savings plans

  • A field experiment in a Swiss Red Cross blood drive provides new evidence for the view that:

    • In some domains, many individuals do not have preferences.

    • Preferences are constructed when they are elicited, & constructing them can be costly.

      Findings is that individuals who have not formed a preference tend to choose the default option in a menu of options, since this permits them to avoid making the (costly) active decision

    • & so a change in the default option leads to swings in behavior

      Stutzer et al. (2011)


  • Login