1 / 57

Asymmetric Information

Asymmetric Information. Asymmetric Information. Transactions can involve a considerable amount of uncertainty can lead to inefficiency when one side has better information The side with better information is said to have private information or asymmetric information. Asymmetric Information.

felix-noble
Download Presentation

Asymmetric Information

An Image/Link below is provided (as is) to download presentation Download Policy: Content on the Website is provided to you AS IS for your information and personal use and may not be sold / licensed / shared on other websites without getting consent from its author. Content is provided to you AS IS for your information and personal use only. Download presentation by click this link. While downloading, if for some reason you are not able to download a presentation, the publisher may have deleted the file from their server. During download, if you can't get a presentation, the file might be deleted by the publisher.

E N D

Presentation Transcript


  1. Asymmetric Information

  2. Asymmetric Information • Transactions can involve a considerable amount of uncertainty • can lead to inefficiency when one side has better information • The side with better information is said to have private information or asymmetric information

  3. Asymmetric Information • Information cost may vary among agents as a result of differences in education and experience about commodity • Examples include • A firm possessing limited information about a potential worker’s abilities • A used car buyer not having complete repair and maintenance history on an auto • An insurance company not knowing risky behavior of a potential insurer

  4. The Value of Contracts • Contractual provisions can be added in order to circumvent some of the inefficiencies associated with asymmetric information • Example: Insurance company can offer lower health insurance premium to customer who submit to medical exams • rarely do they eliminate them

  5. Principal-Agent Model • The party who proposes the contract is called the principal • The party who decides whether or not to accept the contract and then performs under the terms of the contract is the agent • typically the party with asymmetric information

  6. Leading Models • Two models of asymmetric information • the agent’s actions affect the principal, but the principal does not observe the actions directly • called a hidden-action model or a moral hazard model • the agent has private information before signing the contract (his type) • called a hidden-type model or an adverse selection model

  7. First, Second, and Third Best • In a full-information environment, the principal could propose a contract that maximizes joint surplus • could capture all of the surplus for himself, leaving the agent just enough to make him indifferent between agreeing to the contract or not • This is called a first-best contract

  8. First, Second, and Third Best • The contract that maximizes the principal’s surplus subject to the constraint that he is less well informed than the agent is called a second-best contract • Adding further constraints leads to the third best, fourth best, etc.

  9. Hidden Actions • The principal would like the agent to take an action that maximizes their joint surplus • But, the agent’s actions may be unobservable to the principal • the agent will prefer to shirk • Contracts can mitigate shirking by tying compensation to observable outcomes

  10. Hidden Actions • Often, the principal is more concerned with outcomes than actions anyway • may as well condition the contract on outcomes

  11. Hidden Actions • The problem is that the outcome may depend in part on random factors outside of the agent’s control • tying the agent’s compensation to outcomes exposes the agent to risk • if the agent is risk averse, he may require the payment of a risk premium before he will accept the contract

  12. Owner-Manager Relationship • Suppose a firm has one representative owner and one manager • the owner offers a contract to the manager • the manager decides whether to accept the contract and what action e 0 to take • an increase in e increases the firm’s gross profit but is personally costly to the manager (e – effort & time the manager puts in on the job)

  13. Owner-Manager Relationship • The firm’s gross profit is g = e +  • where  represents demand, cost, and other economic factors outside of the agent’s control • assume  ~ (0,2) • c(e) is the manager’s personal disutility from effort / cost of undertaking effort • assume c’(e) > 0 and c’’(e) < 0

  14. Owner-Manager Relationship • If s is the manager’s salary, the firm’s net profit is n = g– s • The risk-neutral owner wishes to maximize the expected value of profit E(n) = E(e +  –s) = e – E(s)

  15. Owner-Manager Relationship • We will assume the manager is risk averse with a constant risk aversion parameter of A > 0 • The manager’s expected utility will be

  16. First-Best (Full info case) • With full information, it is relatively easy to design an optimal salary contract • the owner can pay the manager a salary if he exerts a first-best level of effort and nothing otherwise • for the manager to accept the contract E(u) = s* - c(e*)  0

  17. First-Best • The owner will pay the lowest salary possible [s* = c(e*)] • The owner’s net profit will be E(n) = e* - E(s*) = e* - c(e*) • at the optimum, the marginal cost of effort equals the marginal benefit

  18. Second Best • If the owner cannot observe effort, the contract cannot be conditioned on e • the owner may still induce effort if some of the manager’s salary depends on gross profit • suppose the owner offers a salary such as s(g) = a + bg • a is the fixed salary and b is the power of the incentive scheme

  19. Second Best • This relationship can be viewed as a three-stage game • owner sets the salary (choosing a and b) • the manager decides whether or not to accept the contract • the manager decides how much effort to put forth (conditional on accepting the contract)

  20. Second Best • Because the owner cannot observe e directly and the manager is risk-averse, the second-best effort will be less than the first-best effort • the risk premium adds to the owner’s cost of inducing effort

  21. First- versus Second-Best Effort The owner’s MC is higher in the second best, leading to lower effort by the manager MC in second best c’(e) + risk term MC in first best c’(e) MB 1 e e** e*

  22. Moral Hazard in Insurance • If a person is fully insured, he will have a reduced incentive to undertake precautions • may increase the likelihood of a loss occurring

  23. Moral Hazard in Insurance • The effect of insurance coverage on an individual’s precautions, which may change the likelihood or size of losses, is known as moral hazard

  24. Mathematical Model • Suppose a risk-averse individual faces the possibility of a loss (l) that will reduce his initial wealth (W0) • the probability of loss is  • an individual can reduce this probability by spending more on preventive measures (e)

  25. Mathematical Model • An insurance company offers a contract involving a payment of x to the individual if a loss occurs • the premium is p • If the individual takes the coverage, his expected utility is E[u(W)] = (1-)u(W0-e-p) + ()u(W0-e-p-l+x)

  26. First-Best Insurance Contract • In the first-best case, the insurance company can perfectly monitor e • should set the terms to maximize its expected profit subject to the participation constraint • the expected utility with insurance must be at least as large as the utility without the insurance • will result in full insurance with x = l • the individual will choose the socially efficient level of precaution

  27. Second-Best Insurance Contract • Assume the insurance company cannot monitor e at all • an incentive compatibility constraint must be added • The second-best contract will typically not involve full insurance • exposing the individual to some risk induces him to take some precaution

  28. Hidden Types • In the hidden-type model, the individual has private information about an innate characteristic he cannot choose • the agent’s private information at the time of signing the contract puts him in a better position

  29. Hidden Types • The principal will try to extract as much surplus as possible from agents through clever contract design • include options targeted to every agent type

  30. Nonlinear Pricing • Consider a monopolist who sells to a consumer with private information about his own valuation for the good • The monopolist offers a nonlinear price schedule • menu of different-sized bundles at different prices • larger bundles sell for lower per-unit price

  31. Mathematical Model • Suppose a single consumer obtains surplus from consuming a bundle of q units for which he pays a total tariff of T u = v(q) – T • assume that v’(q) > 0 and v’’(q) < 0 • the consumer’s type is  • H is the “high” type (with probability of ) • L is the “low” type (with probability of 1-) • 0 < L < H

  32. Mathematical Model • Suppose the monopolist has a constant average and marginal cost of c • The monopolist’s profit from selling q units is  = T – cq

  33. First-Best Nonlinear Pricing • In the first-best case, the monopolist observes  • At the optimum v’(q) = c • the marginal social benefit of increased quantity is equal to the marginal social cost

  34. First-Best Nonlinear Pricing This graph shows the consumers’ indifference curves (by type) and the firm’s isoprofit curves T U0H U0L q

  35. First-Best Nonlinear Pricing A is the first-best contract offered to the “high” type and B is the first-best offer to the “low” type T U0H A U0L B q

  36. Second-Best Nonlinear Pricing • Suppose the monopolist cannot observe  • knows the distribution • Choosing A is no longer incentive compatible for the high type • the monopolist must reduce the high-type’s tariff

  37. To keep him from choosing B, the monopolist must reduce the “high” type’s tariff by offering a point like C C Second-Best Nonlinear Pricing The “high” type can reach a higher indifference curve by choosing B T U0H A U2H U0L B q

  38. Second-Best Nonlinear Pricing The monopolist can also alter the “low” type’s bundle to make it less attractive to the high type T U0H A E U2H C U0L B D q q**H q**L

  39. Monopoly Coffee Shop • The college has a single coffee shop • faces a marginal cost of 5 cents per ounce • The representative customer faces an equal probability of being one of two types • a coffee hound (H = 20) • a regular Joe (L = 15) • Assume v(q) = 2q0.5

  40. First Best • Substituting such that marginal cost = marginal benefit, we get q = (/c)2 q*L = 9 q*H = 16 T*L = 90 T*H = 160 E() = 62.5

  41. Incentive Compatibility when Types Are Hidden • The first-best pricing scheme is not incentive compatible if the monopolist cannot observe type • keeping the cup sizes the same, the price for the large cup would have to be reduced by 30 cents • the shop’s expected profit falls to 47.5

  42. Second Best • The shop can do better by reducing the size of the small cup • The size that is second best would be LqL-0.5 = c + (H - L)qL-0.5 q**L = 4 T**L = 60 E() = 50

  43. Adverse Selection in Insurance • Adverse selection is a problem facing insurers where the risky types are more likely to accept an insurance policy and are more expensive to serve • assume policy holders may be one of two types • H = high risk • L = low risk

  44. First Best • The insurer can observe the individual’s risk type • First best involves full insurance • different premiums are charged to each type to extract all surplus

  45. First Best W2 U0L Without insurance each type finds himself at E certainty line U0H B A and B represent full insurance A E W1

  46. Second Best • If the insurer cannot observe type, first-best contracts will not be incentive compatible • if the insurer offered A and B, the high-risk type would choose B • the insurer must change the coverage offered to low-risk individuals to make it unattractive to high-risk individuals

  47. The high-risk type is fully insured, but his premium is higher (than it would be at B) C D The low-risk type is only partially insured First Best W2 U0L U1H certainty line U0H B A E W1

  48. Market Signaling • If the informed player moves first, he can “signal” his type to the other party • the low-risk individual would benefit from providing his type to insurers • he should be willing to pay the difference between his equilibrium and his first-best surplus to issue such a signal

  49. Market for Lemons • Sellers of used cars have more information on the condition of the car • but the act of offering the car for sale can serve as a signal of car quality • it must be below some threshold that would have induced the owner to keep it

  50. Market for Lemons • Suppose there is a continuum of qualities from low-quality lemons to high-quality gems • only the owner knows a car’s type • Because buyers cannot determine the quality, all used cars sell for the same price • function of average car quality

More Related