Binomial models
Download
1 / 111

Binomial Models - PowerPoint PPT Presentation


  • 255 Views
  • Uploaded on

Binomial Models. Dr. San-Lin Chung Department of Finance National Taiwan University. In this lecture, I will cover the following topics: 1. Brief Review of Binomial Model 2. Extensions of the binomial models in the literature 3. Fast and accurate binomial option models

loader
I am the owner, or an agent authorized to act on behalf of the owner, of the copyrighted work described.
capcha
Download Presentation

PowerPoint Slideshow about ' Binomial Models' - dorit


An Image/Link below is provided (as is) to download presentation

Download Policy: Content on the Website is provided to you AS IS for your information and personal use and may not be sold / licensed / shared on other websites without getting consent from its author.While downloading, if for some reason you are not able to download a presentation, the publisher may have deleted the file from their server.


- - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - E N D - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - -
Presentation Transcript
Binomial models

Binomial Models

Dr. San-Lin Chung

Department of Finance

National Taiwan University


In this lecture, I will cover the following topics:

1. Brief Review of Binomial Model

2. Extensions of the binomial models in the literature

3. Fast and accurate binomial option models

4. Binomial models for pricing exotic options

5. Binomial models for other distributions or processes


1 brief review of binomial trees
1. Brief Review of Binomial Trees

  • Binomial trees are frequently used to approximate the movements in the price of a stock or other asset

  • In each small interval of time the stock price is assumed to move up by a proportional amount u or to move down by a proportional amount d


The main idea of binomial option pricing theory is pricing by arbitrage. If one can formulate a portfolio to replicate the payoff of an option, then the option price should equal to the price of the replicating portfolio if the market has no arbitrage opportunity.Binomial model is a complete market model, i.e. options can be replicated using stock and risk-free bond (two states next period, two assets).On the other hand, trinomial model is not a complete market model.


Generalization figure 10 2 page 202
Generalization by arbitrage. If one can formulate a portfolio to replicate the payoff of an option, then the option price should equal to the price of the replicating portfolio if the market has no arbitrage opportunity.(Figure 10.2, page 202)

  • A derivative lasts for time T and is dependent on a stock

S0 u

ƒu

S0

ƒ

S0d

ƒd


Generalization continued
Generalization by arbitrage. If one can formulate a portfolio to replicate the payoff of an option, then the option price should equal to the price of the replicating portfolio if the market has no arbitrage opportunity.(continued)

  • Consider the portfolio that is long D shares and short 1 derivative

  • The portfolio is riskless when S0uD – ƒu = S0dD – ƒd or

S0 uD – ƒu

S0– f

S0dD – ƒd


Generalization continued1
Generalization by arbitrage. If one can formulate a portfolio to replicate the payoff of an option, then the option price should equal to the price of the replicating portfolio if the market has no arbitrage opportunity.(continued)

  • Value of the portfolio at time Tis S0uD – ƒu

  • Value of the portfolio today is (S0uD – ƒu )e–rT

  • Another expression for the portfolio value today is S0D – f

  • Hence ƒ = S0D – (S0uD – ƒu)e–rT


Generalization continued2
Generalization by arbitrage. If one can formulate a portfolio to replicate the payoff of an option, then the option price should equal to the price of the replicating portfolio if the market has no arbitrage opportunity.(continued)

  • Substituting for D we obtain

    ƒ = [ p ƒu + (1 – p )ƒd ]e–rT

    where


Risk neutral valuation
Risk-Neutral Valuation by arbitrage. If one can formulate a portfolio to replicate the payoff of an option, then the option price should equal to the price of the replicating portfolio if the market has no arbitrage opportunity.

  • ƒ = [ p ƒu + (1 – p )ƒd ]e-rT

  • The variables p and (1– p ) can be interpreted as the risk-neutral probabilities of up and down movements

  • The value of a derivative is its expected payoff in a risk-neutral world discounted at the risk-free rate

S0u

ƒu

p

S0

ƒ

S0d

ƒd

(1– p )


Irrelevance of stock s expected return
Irrelevance of Stock’s Expected Return by arbitrage. If one can formulate a portfolio to replicate the payoff of an option, then the option price should equal to the price of the replicating portfolio if the market has no arbitrage opportunity.

When we are valuing an option in terms of the underlying stock the expected return on the stock is irrelevant


Movements in time d t figure 18 1
Movements in Time by arbitrage. If one can formulate a portfolio to replicate the payoff of an option, then the option price should equal to the price of the replicating portfolio if the market has no arbitrage opportunity.dt(Figure 18.1)

Su

p

S

1 – p

Sd


Tree parameters for a nondividend paying stock
Tree Parameters for a by arbitrage. If one can formulate a portfolio to replicate the payoff of an option, then the option price should equal to the price of the replicating portfolio if the market has no arbitrage opportunity.Nondividend Paying Stock

  • We choose the tree parameters p, u, and d so that the tree gives correct values for the mean & standard deviation of the stock price changes in a risk-neutral world

    erdt= pu + (1– p )d

    s2dt = pu2 + (1– p )d 2 – [pu + (1– p )d ]2

  • A further condition often imposed is u = 1/ d


2 tree parameters for a nondividend paying stock equations 18 4 to 18 7
2. Tree Parameters for a by arbitrage. If one can formulate a portfolio to replicate the payoff of an option, then the option price should equal to the price of the replicating portfolio if the market has no arbitrage opportunity.Nondividend Paying Stock(Equations 18.4 to 18.7)

When dt is small, a solution to the equations is


The complete tree figure 18 2
The Complete Tree by arbitrage. If one can formulate a portfolio to replicate the payoff of an option, then the option price should equal to the price of the replicating portfolio if the market has no arbitrage opportunity.(Figure 18.2)

S0u4

S0u3

S0u2

S0u2

S0u

S0u

S0

S0

S0

S0d

S0d

S0d2

S0d2

S0d3

S0d4


Backwards induction
Backwards Induction by arbitrage. If one can formulate a portfolio to replicate the payoff of an option, then the option price should equal to the price of the replicating portfolio if the market has no arbitrage opportunity.

  • We know the value of the option at the final nodes

  • We work back through the tree using risk-neutral valuation to calculate the value of the option at each node, testing for early exercise when appropriate


Example put option
Example: Put Option by arbitrage. If one can formulate a portfolio to replicate the payoff of an option, then the option price should equal to the price of the replicating portfolio if the market has no arbitrage opportunity.

S0= 50; X = 50; r =10%; s = 40%;

T = 5 months = 0.4167;

dt = 1 month = 0.0833

The parameters imply

u = 1.1224; d = 0.8909;

a = 1.0084; p = 0.5076


Example continued figure 18 3
Example (continued) by arbitrage. If one can formulate a portfolio to replicate the payoff of an option, then the option price should equal to the price of the replicating portfolio if the market has no arbitrage opportunity.Figure 18.3


Trees and dividend yields
Trees and Dividend Yields by arbitrage. If one can formulate a portfolio to replicate the payoff of an option, then the option price should equal to the price of the replicating portfolio if the market has no arbitrage opportunity.

  • When a stock price pays continuous dividends at rate q we construct the tree in the same way but set a = e(r – q )dt

  • As with Black-Scholes:

    • For options on stock indices,qequals the dividend yield on the index

    • For options on a foreign currency, qequals the foreign risk-free rate

    • For options on futures contracts q = r


Binomial tree for dividend paying stock
Binomial Tree for Dividend Paying Stock by arbitrage. If one can formulate a portfolio to replicate the payoff of an option, then the option price should equal to the price of the replicating portfolio if the market has no arbitrage opportunity.

  • Procedure:

    • Draw the tree for the stock price less the present value of the dividends

    • Create a new tree by adding the present value of the dividends at each node

  • This ensures that the tree recombines and makes assumptions similar to those when the Black-Scholes model is used


II. Literature Review (1/5) by arbitrage. If one can formulate a portfolio to replicate the payoff of an option, then the option price should equal to the price of the replicating portfolio if the market has no arbitrage opportunity.

There have been many extensions of the CRR model. The extensions can be classified into five directions.

The first direction consists in modifying the lattice to improve the accuracy and computational efficiency.

Boyle (1988)

Breen (1991)

Broadie and Detemple (1996)

Figlewski and Gao (1999)

Heston and Zhou (2000)


II. Literature Review (2/5) by arbitrage. If one can formulate a portfolio to replicate the payoff of an option, then the option price should equal to the price of the replicating portfolio if the market has no arbitrage opportunity.

The second branch of the binomial OPM literature has incorporated multiple random assets.

Boyle (1988)

Boyle, Evnine, and Gibbs (1989)

Madan, Milne, and Shefrin (1989)

He (1990)

Ho, Stapleton, and Subrahmanyam (1995)

Chen, Chung, and Yang (2002)


II. Literature Review (3/5) by arbitrage. If one can formulate a portfolio to replicate the payoff of an option, then the option price should equal to the price of the replicating portfolio if the market has no arbitrage opportunity.

The third direction of extensions consists in showing the convergence property of the binomial OPM.

Cox, Ross, and Rubinstein (1979)

Amin and Khanna (1994)

He (1990)

Nelson and Ramaswamy (1990)


II. Literature Review (4/5) by arbitrage. If one can formulate a portfolio to replicate the payoff of an option, then the option price should equal to the price of the replicating portfolio if the market has no arbitrage opportunity.

The fourth direction of the literature generalizes the

binomial model to price options under stochastic volatility and/or stochastic interest rates.

Stochastic interest rate: Black, Derman, and Toy (1990), Nelson and Ramaswamy (1990), Hull and White (1994), and others.

Stochastic volatility: Amin (1991) and Ho, Stapleton, and Subrahmanyam (1995) Ritchken and Trevor (1999)


II. Literature Review (5/5) by arbitrage. If one can formulate a portfolio to replicate the payoff of an option, then the option price should equal to the price of the replicating portfolio if the market has no arbitrage opportunity.

The fifth extension of the CRR model focus on adjusting the standard multiplicative-binomial model to price exotic options, especially path-dependent options.

Asian options: Hull and White (1993) and Dai and Lyuu (2002).

Barrier options: Boyle and Lau(1994), Ritchken (1995), Boyle and Tian (1999), and others.


3 alternative binomial tree 3 1 jarrow and rudd 1982
3. Alternative Binomial Tree by arbitrage. If one can formulate a portfolio to replicate the payoff of an option, then the option price should equal to the price of the replicating portfolio if the market has no arbitrage opportunity.3.1 Jarrow and Rudd (1982)

Instead of setting u = 1/d we can set each of the 2 probabilities to 0.5 and


3 2 trinomial tree page 409

Su by arbitrage. If one can formulate a portfolio to replicate the payoff of an option, then the option price should equal to the price of the replicating portfolio if the market has no arbitrage opportunity.

pu

pm

S

S

pd

Sd

3.2 Trinomial Tree (Page 409)


3 3 adaptive mesh model
3.3 Adaptive Mesh Model by arbitrage. If one can formulate a portfolio to replicate the payoff of an option, then the option price should equal to the price of the replicating portfolio if the market has no arbitrage opportunity.

  • This is a way of grafting a high resolution tree on to a low resolution tree

  • We need high resolution in the region of the tree close to the strike price and option maturity


3 4 bbs and bbsr
3.4 BBS and BBSR by arbitrage. If one can formulate a portfolio to replicate the payoff of an option, then the option price should equal to the price of the replicating portfolio if the market has no arbitrage opportunity.

The Binomial Black & Scholes (BBS) method is

proposed by Broadie and Detemple (1996). The

BBS method is identical to the CRR method, except

that at the time step just before option maturity the

Black and Scholes formula replaces at all the nodes.


3 5 tian 1999 1 3
3.5 Tian (1999) by arbitrage. If one can formulate a portfolio to replicate the payoff of an option, then the option price should equal to the price of the replicating portfolio if the market has no arbitrage opportunity.(1/3)

The second method was put forward by Tian(1999) termed

“flexible binomial model”. To construct the so-called

flexible binomial model, the following specification is

proposed:

where λ is an arbitrary constant, called the “tilt

parameter”. It is an extra degree of freedom over the

standard binomial model. In order to have “nonnegative

probability”, the tilt parameter must satisfy the inequality (8)

after jumps, u and d, are redefined.


3 6 heston and zhou 2000
3.6 Heston and Zhou (2000) by arbitrage. If one can formulate a portfolio to replicate the payoff of an option, then the option price should equal to the price of the replicating portfolio if the market has no arbitrage opportunity.

Heston and Zhou (2000) show that the accuracy or rate of

convergence of binomial method depend, crucially on the

smoothness of the payoff function. They have given an

approach that is to smooth the payoff function. Intuitively,

if the payoff function at singular points can be smoothing,

the binomial recursion might be more accurate. Hence they

let G(x) be the smoothed one;

where g(x) is the actual payoff function.


3 7 leisen and reimer 1996
3.7 Leisen and Reimer (1996) by arbitrage. If one can formulate a portfolio to replicate the payoff of an option, then the option price should equal to the price of the replicating portfolio if the market has no arbitrage opportunity.


3 7 leisen and reimer 19961
3.7 Leisen and Reimer (1996) by arbitrage. If one can formulate a portfolio to replicate the payoff of an option, then the option price should equal to the price of the replicating portfolio if the market has no arbitrage opportunity.


3 8 wand 2002 jfm
3.8 WAND (2002, JFM) by arbitrage. If one can formulate a portfolio to replicate the payoff of an option, then the option price should equal to the price of the replicating portfolio if the market has no arbitrage opportunity.


3 8 wand 2002 jfm1
3.8 WAND (2002, JFM) by arbitrage. If one can formulate a portfolio to replicate the payoff of an option, then the option price should equal to the price of the replicating portfolio if the market has no arbitrage opportunity.

WAND (2002) showed that the binomial option pricing errors are related to the node positioning and they defined a ratio for node positioning.


3 8 wand 2002 jfm2
3.8 WAND (2002, JFM) by arbitrage. If one can formulate a portfolio to replicate the payoff of an option, then the option price should equal to the price of the replicating portfolio if the market has no arbitrage opportunity.

The relationship between the errors and node positioning.


3 9 gcrr model
3.9 GCRR model by arbitrage. If one can formulate a portfolio to replicate the payoff of an option, then the option price should equal to the price of the replicating portfolio if the market has no arbitrage opportunity.

Theorem 1.In the GCRR model, the three parameters are as

follows:

where is a stretch parameter which determines the shape of

the binomial tree. Moreover, when , i.e., the number of time

steps n grows to infinity, the GCRR binomial prices will converge

to the Black-Scholes formulae for European options.

  • Obviously the CRR model is a special case of our GCRR model when .

  • We can easily allocate the strike price at one of the final nodes.


3 9 gcrr model1
3.9 GCRR model by arbitrage. If one can formulate a portfolio to replicate the payoff of an option, then the option price should equal to the price of the replicating portfolio if the market has no arbitrage opportunity.

Various Types of GCRR models:


4 binomial models for exotic options
4. Binomial models for exotic options by arbitrage. If one can formulate a portfolio to replicate the payoff of an option, then the option price should equal to the price of the replicating portfolio if the market has no arbitrage opportunity.

Topics:

1. Path dependent options using trees

  • Lookback options

  • Barrier options

    2. Options where there are two stochastic variables (exchange option, maximum option, etc.)


Path dependence the traditional view
Path Dependence: by arbitrage. If one can formulate a portfolio to replicate the payoff of an option, then the option price should equal to the price of the replicating portfolio if the market has no arbitrage opportunity.The Traditional View

  • Backwards induction works well for American options. It cannot be used for path-dependent options

  • Monte Carlo simulation works well for path-dependent options; it cannot be used for American options


Extension of backwards induction
Extension of Backwards Induction by arbitrage. If one can formulate a portfolio to replicate the payoff of an option, then the option price should equal to the price of the replicating portfolio if the market has no arbitrage opportunity.

  • Backwards induction can be used for some path-dependent options

  • We will first illustrate the methodology using lookback options and then show how it can be used for Asian options


Lookback example page 462
Lookback Example by arbitrage. If one can formulate a portfolio to replicate the payoff of an option, then the option price should equal to the price of the replicating portfolio if the market has no arbitrage opportunity.(Page 462)

  • Consider an American lookback put on a stock where

    S = 50, s = 40%, r = 10%, dt = 1 month & the life of the option is 3 months

  • Payoff is Smax-ST

  • We can value the deal by considering all possible values of the maximum stock price at each node

    (This example is presented to illustrate the methodology. A more efficient ways of handling American lookbacks is in Section 20.6.)


Example an american lookback put option figure 20 2 page 463

70.70 by arbitrage. If one can formulate a portfolio to replicate the payoff of an option, then the option price should equal to the price of the replicating portfolio if the market has no arbitrage opportunity.

70.70

0.00

62.99

62.99

56.12

56.12

3.36

62.99 56.12

6.87

0.00

56.12

50.00

50.00

5.47

4.68

56.12 50.00

44.55

44.55

6.12

2.66

56.12 50.00

50.00

11.57

5.45

36.69

6.38

50.00

35.36

10.31

50.00

14.64

Example: An American Lookback Put Option (Figure 20.2, page 463)

S0 = 50, s = 40%, r = 10%, dt = 1 month,

A


Why the approach works
Why the Approach Works by arbitrage. If one can formulate a portfolio to replicate the payoff of an option, then the option price should equal to the price of the replicating portfolio if the market has no arbitrage opportunity.

This approach works for lookback options because

  • The payoff depends on just 1 function of the path followed by the stock price. (We will refer to this as a “path function”)

  • The value of the path function at a node can be calculated from the stock price at the node & from the value of the function at the immediately preceding node

  • The number of different values of the path function at a node does not grow too fast as we increase the number of time steps on the tree


Extensions of the approach
Extensions of the Approach by arbitrage. If one can formulate a portfolio to replicate the payoff of an option, then the option price should equal to the price of the replicating portfolio if the market has no arbitrage opportunity.

  • The approach can be extended so that there are no limits on the number of alternative values of the path function at a node

  • The basic idea is that it is not necessary to consider every possible value of the path function

  • It is sufficient to consider a relatively small number of representative values of the function at each node


Working forward
Working Forward by arbitrage. If one can formulate a portfolio to replicate the payoff of an option, then the option price should equal to the price of the replicating portfolio if the market has no arbitrage opportunity.

  • First work forwards through the tree calculating the max and min values of the “path function” at each node

  • Next choose representative values of the path function that span the range between the min and the max

    • Simplest approach: choose the min, the max, and N equally spaced values between the min and max


Backwards induction1
Backwards Induction by arbitrage. If one can formulate a portfolio to replicate the payoff of an option, then the option price should equal to the price of the replicating portfolio if the market has no arbitrage opportunity.

  • We work backwards through the tree in the usual way carrying out calculations for each of the alternative values of the path function that are considered at a node

  • When we require the value of the derivative at a node for a value of the path function that is not explicitly considered at that node, we use linear or quadratic interpolation


Part of tree to calculate value of an option on the arithmetic average

S = 54.68 by arbitrage. If one can formulate a portfolio to replicate the payoff of an option, then the option price should equal to the price of the replicating portfolio if the market has no arbitrage opportunity.

Y

Average S

47.99

51.12

54.26

57.39

Option Price

7.575

8.101

8.635

9.178

S = 50.00

Average S

46.65

49.04

51.44

53.83

Option Price

5.642

5.923

6.206

6.492

X

S = 45.72

Average S

43.88

46.75

49.61

52.48

Option Price

3.430

3.750

4.079

4.416

Z

Part of Tree to Calculate Value of an Option on the Arithmetic Average

0.5056

0.4944

S=50, X=50, s=40%, r=10%, T=1yr, dt=0.05yr. We are at time 4dt


Part of tree to calculate value of an option on the arithmetic average continued
Part of Tree to Calculate Value of an Option on the Arithmetic Average (continued)

Consider Node X when the average of 5 observations is 51.44

Node Y: If this is reached, the average becomes 51.98. The option price is interpolated as 8.247

Node Z: If this is reached, the average becomes 50.49. The option price is interpolated as 4.182

Node X: value is

(0.5056×8.247 + 0.4944×4.182)e–0.1×0.05 = 6.206


A more efficient approach for lookbacks section 20 6 page 465
A More Efficient Approach for Lookbacks Arithmetic Average (continued)(Section 20.6, page 465)


Using trees with barriers section 20 7 page 467
Using Trees with Barriers Arithmetic Average (continued)(Section 20.7, page 467)

  • When trees are used to value options with barriers, convergence tends to be slow

  • The slow convergence arises from the fact that the barrier is inaccurately specified by the tree


True barrier vs tree barrier for a knockout option the binomial tree case
True Barrier vs Tree Barrier for a Arithmetic Average (continued)Knockout Option: The Binomial Tree Case

Barrier assumed by tree

True barrier


True barrier vs tree barrier for a knockout option the trinomial tree case
True Barrier vs Tree Barrier for a Knockout Option: The Trinomial Tree Case

Barrier assumed by tree

True barrier


Bumping up against the barrier with the binomial method jd boyle and lau 1994
Bumping Up Against the Barrier with the Binomial Method, Trinomial Tree CaseJD, Boyle and Lau (1994)


On pricing barrier options jd ritchken 1995
On Pricing Barrier Options, Trinomial Tree CaseJD, Ritchken (1995)


Complex barrier options

Complex Barrier Options Trinomial Tree Case

Cheuk and Vorst (1996)

Time varying barrier

Double barriers


Alternative solutions to the problem
Alternative Solutions Trinomial Tree Caseto the Problem

  • Ensure that nodes always lie on the barriers

  • Adjust for the fact that nodes do not lie on the barriers

  • Use adaptive mesh

    In all cases a trinomial tree is preferable to a binomial tree


Multi asset case
Multi-Asset Case Trinomial Tree Case

Reference:

  • Boyle, P. P., J. Evnine, and S. Gibbs, 1989, Numerical Evaluation of Multivariate Contingent Claims, The Review of Financial Studies, 2, 241-250.

  • Chen, R. R., S. L. Chung, and T. T. Yang, 2002, Option Pricing in a Multi-Asset, Complete Market Economy, Journal of Financial and Quantitative Analysis, 37, 649-666.

  •   Ho, T. S., R. C. Stapleton, and M. G. Subrahmanyam, 1995, Multivariate Binomial Approximations for Asset Prices with Nonstationary Variance and Covariance Characteristics, The Review of Financial Studies, 8, 1125-1152.

  •  Kamrad, B., and P. Ritchken, 1991, Multinomial Approximating Models for Options with k State Variables, Management Science, 37, 1640-1652.

  •  Madan, D. B., F. Milne, and H. Shefrin, 1989, The Multinomial Option Pricing Model and Its Brownian and Poisson Limits, The Review of Financial Studies, 2, 251-265.


Modeling two correlated variables
Modeling Two Correlated Variables Trinomial Tree Case

Consider a two-asset case:

Under the first approach: Transform variables so that they are not correlated & build the tree in the transformed variables


Modeling two correlated variables1
Modeling Two Correlated Variables Trinomial Tree Case

We define two new uncorrelated variables:

These variables follow the processes:

where and are uncorrelated Wiener processes.

At each node of the tree, and can be calculated from and using the inverse relationships


Modeling two correlated variables2
Modeling Two Correlated Variables Trinomial Tree Case

Take the correlation into account by adjusting the position of the nodes:


Modeling two correlated variables3
Modeling Two Correlated Variables Trinomial Tree Case

Take the correlation into account by adjusting the probabilities


Multi asset tree model under complete market economy
Multi-Asset tree model under complete market economy Trinomial Tree Case

Chen, R. R., S. L. Chung, and T. T. Yang, 2002, Option Pricing in a Multi-Asset, Complete-Market Economy, Journal of Financial and Quantitative Analysis, Vol. 37, No. 4, 649-666.

With two uncorrelated Brownian motions with equal variances, the three points, A, B, and C, are best to be “equally” apart from each other. This can be achieved most easily by choosing 3 points, located 120 degrees from each other, on the circumference of a circle, as shown in Exhibit 2.


Multi asset tree model under complete market economy1
Multi-Asset tree model under complete market economy Trinomial Tree Case

To incorporate the correlation between the two Brownian motions, we then rotate the axes, as shown in Exhibit 3.


Multi asset tree model under complete market economy2
Multi-Asset tree model under complete market economy Trinomial Tree Case

Proposition 2

The rotation of the axes is defined as follows:

where  is the rotation angle of the x-axis counterclockwise and y-axis clockwise. After rotation, we have:

  • the means and the variances of the rotated ellipse remain unchanged and

  • the correlation is a function of the rotation degree :


Multi asset tree model under complete market economy3
Multi-Asset tree model under complete market economy Trinomial Tree Case

Finally, for any given time, t, the next period stock prices are:




How to construct a recombined binomial trinomial tree under time varying volatility
how to construct a recombined binomial/trinomial tree under time-varying volatility?

  • Amin (1991) suggested changing the number of steps (or dt) such that the tree is recombined.

  • Ho, Stapleton, and Subrahmanyam (1995) suggested using two steps to match the conditional and unconditional volatility and unconditional mean.

  • Using the trinomial tree of Boyle (1988) or Ritchken (1995). See next page.

    Ref : Amin (1995, pp.39-40) has a very nice discussion on this issue.

    Amin, 1995, Option Pricing Trees, Journal of Derivatives,

    34-46.


Amin 1991 1 2
Amin (1991) time-varying volatility? (1/2)

Assume that the underlying asset price follows

dS = rSdt + (t)Sdz

then the annual variance of the asset price over the period

[0, T] is

Let N be the number of time steps desired, then .

The time step for each period is denoted as h(t), h(2t), …, h(nt). Amin let


Amin 1991 2 2
Amin (1991) time-varying volatility? (2/2)

In this case, the tree is recombining because

where u(t), u(2t), …, u(nt) are size of up movement at

each period.


Following Boyle (1988), the asset price, at any given time, time-varying volatility?

can move into three possible states, up, down, or middle, in

the next period. If S denotes the asset price at time t, then at

time t + dt, the prices will be Su, Sd, or Sm. The parameters

are defined as follows

and

where   1, the dispersion parameter, is chosen freely as

long as the resulting probabilities are positive. Let i


represent the instantaneous volatility at time time-varying volatility? ti, then we can

set

In this case the tree is recombining and the probability of

each branch is of course time varying.


To guarantee that the resulting probabilities are positive, we

must carefully choose dt and . Roughly speaking, dt must

be small enough such that

For , as discussed in Boyle (1988), its values must be larger

than 1. Denote the maximum and minimum of the

instantaneous volatility for the period from time 0 to T as

max and min. Then


We can arbitrarily set we max as 1.1 and then all other i will be

larger than 1 automatically.

Ref :

Boyle, P. (1988), A Lattice Framework for Option Pricing with Two State Variables, Journal of Financial and Quantitative Analysis, 23, 1-12.



Reference: we

1. Hilliard, J. E., and A. Schwartz, Pricing Options on Traded Assets under Stochastic Interest Rates and Volatility: A Binomial Approach, Journal of Financial Engineering, 6, 281-305.

 2. Hilliard, J. E., A. L. Schwartz, and A. L. Tucker, 1996, Bivariate Binomial Options Pricing with Generalized Interest Rate Processes, Journal of Financial Research, 14, 585-602.

3. Nelson, D. B., and K. Ramaswamy, 1990, Simple Binomial Processes as Diffusion Approximations in Financial Models, Review of Financial Studies, 3, 393-430.

4. Ritchken, P., and R. Trevor, 1999, Pricing Option under Generalized GARCH and Stochastic Volatility Processes, Journal of Finance, 54, 377-402.

5. Hillard, J. E., and A. Schwartz, 2005, “Pricing European and American Derivatives under a Jump-Diffusion Process: A Bivariate Tree Approach,” Journal of Financial and Quantitative Analysis, 40, 671-691.

6. Camara, A., and S. L. Chung, 2006, Option Pricing for the Transformed-Binomial Class, Journal of Futures Markets, Vol. 26, No. 8, 759-788.


Nelson and Ramaswamy (1990) we

Nelson and Ramaswamy (1990) proposed a general tree method to approximate diffusion processes.

Generally a binomial or trinomial tree is not recombined because the volatility is not a constant. Nelson and Ramaswamy (1990) suggested a transformation of the variable such that the transformed variable has a constant volatility.



Nelson and Ramaswamy (1990) we

For example, under the CEV model:


Nelson and Ramaswamy (1990) we

For example, under the CIR model:


Hilliard schwartz stochastic volatility
Hilliard-Schwartz: we Stochastic Volatility

The asset price and return volatility are assumed to follow:

dS = msdt + f(S)h(V)dZs

dV = mvdt + bVdZv (1)

Under Q measure ms=S(r - d).

First of all, make the following transformation to obtain a unit variance variable Y:




Binomial tree for y and trinomial tree for q

Y variable 2, 2

Y1, 1

Y0, 0

Y2, 0

Y1, -1

Y2, -2

Q2, 2

Q1, 1

Q2, 1

Q0, 0

Q2, 0

Q1, 0

Q2, -1

Q1, -1

Q2, -2

T/n = h : 0 1 2

Binomial tree for Y and trinomial tree for Q


Option pricing under garch
Option Pricing under GARCH variable

Ritchken, P., and R. Trevor, 1999, Pricing Option under Generalized GARCH and Stochastic Volatility Processes, Journal of Finance, 54, 377-402.

GARCH model:

The main idea is to keep the spanning of the tree flexible, i.e. the size of up or down movements can be adjusted to match the conditional variance.


Option pricing for the transformed binomial class
Option Pricing for the Transformed-Binomial Class variable

AntÓnio Câmara1 and San-Lin Chung2

January 2004

  • School of Management, University of Michigan-Flint, 3118 William S. White Building, Flint, MI 48502-1950. Tel: (810) 762-3268, Fax: (810) 762-3282, Email: [email protected]

  • Department of Finance, The Management School, National Taiwan University, Taipei 106, Taiwan. Tel:886-2-23676909, Fax:886-2-23660764, Email: [email protected]


Abstract variable

This paper generalizes the seminal Cox-Ross-Rubinstein (1979) binomial option pricing model (OPM) to all members of the class of transformed-binomial pricing processes. Our investigation addresses issues related with asset pricing modeling, hedging strategies, and option pricing. We derive explicit formulae for (1) replicating or hedging portfolios; (2) risk-neutral transformed-binomial probabilities; (3) limiting transformed-normal distributions; and (4) the value of contingent claims. We also study the properties of the transformed-binomial class of asset pricing rocesses. We illustrate the results of the paper with several examples.


I. Introduction (1/7) variable

multiplicative-binomial option pricing model: Cox, Ross, and Rubinstein (1979), Rendlemen and Bartter (1979), and Sharpe (1978)

pricing by arbitrage: According to this rule, when there are no arbitrage opportunities, if a portfolio of stocks and bonds replicates the payoffs of an option then the option must have the same current price as its replicating portfolio.


I. Introduction (6/7) variable

Third, this paper provides a class of distributions that may explain observed option prices (or implied volatilities).


Multiplicative-binomial (hereafter, variable M-binomial) model:

This M-binomial model assumes that u = 2 and d = 0.5.


The S variable L-binomial model with a lower bound  at maturity:

For example, if r = 1.25 and  = 10 then this SL-binomial model assumes that u = 2.1429 and d = 0.3571.


The following S variable U-binomial model:

In this SU-binomial model, it is assumed that u = 1.4107 and d = 0.7106.


The following S variable B-binomial model with a threshold :

For example, if  = 300 then this SB-binomial model

assumes that u = 2.5 and d = 0.4545.


The S variable L-binomial model

Following Johnson (1949), the transformation for the SL-binomial is defined as the following in this article:


The S variable U-binomial model

The transformation for the SU-binomial model is defined as:


The S variable B-binomial model

The third example considered in this paper is the SB-

binomial model, corresponding to the SB-normal model of Johnson (1949). The transformation for the SB-binomial model is as follows:


This figure shows the convergence pattern resulting from option price calculations with the SL-binomial model. We use the following selection of parameters: S = 100, K = 100, r = 0.1,  = 20, t = 1.0,  = 0.25.


This figure shows the convergence pattern resulting from option price calculations with the SU-binomial model. We use the following selection of parameters: S = 100, K = 100, r = 0.1, t = 1.0,  = 0.25.


This figure shows the convergence pattern resulting from option price calculations with the

option price calculations with the SB-binomial model. We

use the following selection of parameters: S = 100, K =100, r = 0.1,  = 300, t = 1.0,  = 0.25.


ad