1 / 84

On the Mathematics and Economics Assumptions of Continuous-Time Models

On the Mathematics and Economics Assumptions of Continuous-Time Models. BaoheWang Baohewang0592@sina.com. 3.1 Introduction. This chapter attempts to

clarice
Download Presentation

On the Mathematics and Economics Assumptions of Continuous-Time Models

An Image/Link below is provided (as is) to download presentation Download Policy: Content on the Website is provided to you AS IS for your information and personal use and may not be sold / licensed / shared on other websites without getting consent from its author. Content is provided to you AS IS for your information and personal use only. Download presentation by click this link. While downloading, if for some reason you are not able to download a presentation, the publisher may have deleted the file from their server. During download, if you can't get a presentation, the file might be deleted by the publisher.

E N D

Presentation Transcript


  1. On the Mathematics and Economics Assumptions of Continuous-Time Models BaoheWang Baohewang0592@sina.com

  2. 3.1 Introduction • This chapter attempts to (1) bridge the gap by using only elementary probability theory and calculus to derive the basic theorems required for continuous time analysis. (2) make explicit the economics assumptions implicitly embedded in the mathematical assumption.

  3. The general approach is to keep the assumption as weak as possible. • But we need make a choice between the losses in generality and the reduction in mathematical complexity.

  4. The substantive contributions of continuous time analysis to financial economic theory: (1) trading take place continuously in time (2) the underlying stochastic variables follow diffusion type motions with continuous sample paths • The twin assumptions lead to a set of behavioral equations for intertemporal portfolio selection that are both simpler and rich than those derived from the corresponding discrete trading model.

  5. The continuous trading is an abstraction from physical reality. • If the length of time between revisions is very short, the continuous trading solution will be a approximation to the discrete trading solution. • The application of continuous time analysis in the empirical study of financial economic data is more recent and less developed.

  6. In early studies, we assume that the logarithm of the ratio of successive prices had a Gaussian distribution. • But the sample characteristics of the time series were frequently inconsistent with these assumed population properties. • Attempts to resolve these discrepancies proceeded along two separate paths.

  7. The first maintains the independent increments and stationarity assumptions but replaces the Gaussian with a more general stable (Parato-Levy) distribution. • The stable family frequently fit the tails of the empirical distributions better than the Gaussian. • But there is little empirical evidence to support adoption of the stable Paretian hypothesis over that of any leptokurtotic distribution.

  8. Moreover, the infinite variance property of the non-Gaussian stable distributions implis : (1) most of our statistical tools, which are based upon finite-moment assumptions are useless. (2) the first-moment or expected value of the arithmetic price change does not exist.

  9. The second, Cootner (1964) consider the alternative path of finite-moment processes whose distributions are nonstationary . • The general continuous time framework requires that the underlying process be a mixture of diffusion and Poisson-directed processes. • The general continuous time framework can accommodate a wide range of specific hypotheses including the “ reflecting barrier” model.

  10. Rosenberg (1972) shows that a Gaussion model with a changing variance rate appear to explain the observed fat-tail characteristics of return. • Rosenberg (1980) has developed statistical techniques for estimating the parameters of continuous time processes. • As discussed by Merton, If the parameters are slowly varying functions of time, then it is possible to exploit the different “ time scales” to identify and estimate these parameters.

  11. The second distribution still required more research before a judgment can be made as to the success of this approach. • Their finite moment properties make the development of hypothesis tests considerably easier for these processes than for the stable Pareto-Levy processes.

  12. With this as a background, we development the assumptions of continuous time models. • If denote the price of a security at time t, the change in the price of the security: where h denote the trading horizon, , denote

  13. The continuous time trading interval assumption implies that the trading interval h is equal to the continuous time infinitesimal dt • Note: it is unreasonable to assume that the equilibrium distribution of returns on a security over a specified time period will be invariant to the trading interval for that security. • Because investors’ optimal demand function will depend upon how frequently they can revise their portfolio.

  14. Define the random variables by: • is the unanticipated price change in the security between and , conditional on being at time . • Because for , hence the partial sums form a martingale. • The theory of martingales is usually associated in the financial economics literature with the “ Efficient Marker Hypothesis”.

  15. Two economics assumptions: • Assumption 1: For each finite time interval [0,T] there exists a number , independent of the number of trading intervals n, such that where . • Assumption 2: For each finite time interval [0,T], there exists a number , independent of n, such that .

  16. The second assumption rules out the variance become unbounded such as Pareto-Levy stable distribution with infinite variance. • Assumption 3: There exists a number independent of n, such that for where and • This assumption rules out the possibility that all the uncertainty in the unanticipated price change over [0,T] is concentrated in a few of the many trading periods, such as lottery ticket.

  17. Proposition 3.1: If Assumption 1,2,3 hold, then That is, and and is asymptotically proportional to h where the proportionality factor is positive. Proof: Suppose then

  18. Therefore From Assumption 3 and 2 where , hence From Assumption 3 and1 where hence

  19. Suppose that can take on any one of m distinct values denoted by where m is finite. • Suppose that there exist a number , independent of n, such than . • If information available as of time zero}, then from Proposition 3.1 it follow that: and because m is finite it follows that: for every j. • Without lost generally, we assume for every j .

  20. Assumption 4: For and are sufficiently “well-behaved” functions of that there exist numbers and such that and . • This assumption is stronger than is necessary. • From Assumption 4, we have So • This say that “ the larger the magnitude of the outcome, the smaller the likelihood that the even will occur.

  21. Because and is bounded , both and must be nonnegative, and therefore, we have: • We can partition its outcomes into three type: (1) “type I” outcome is one such that . (2) “type II” outcome is one such that (3) “type III” outcome is one such that

  22. Let J denote the set of events j such that the outcomes are of type I. • For and therefore . • For , . • So for small trading intervals h, virtually all observations of will be type I outcomes, and therefore an apt name for might be “ the set of rare events.”.

  23. 3.2 Continuous-Sample-Path Processes With “No Rare Events” • In this section, it is assumed that all possible outcomes for are of type I, and therefore is empty. • Define , denote the conditional expected dollar return per unit time on the security.

  24. Assumption 5: For every h, it is assumed that exists, and that there exists a number , independent of h, such that . • This assumption ensures that for all securities with a finite price the expected rate of return per unit time over the trading horizon is finite. • From before formula, we have:

  25. Proposition 3.2: If, for all possible outcomes for are type I outcomes, then the continuous-time sample path for the price of the security will be continuous. • Proof: Let A necessary and sufficient condition for continuity of the sample path for X is that, for every . Define , so For every define function as the solution of .

  26. Because and are , for every . Therefore, for every h, , , and hence as . • The sample for X(t) is continuous, but it is almost nowhere differentiable. • Which diverges as .

  27. So we need a generalized calculus and corresponding theory of stochastic differential equations. • Some moment properties for .

  28. for Hence, the unconditional Nth central and noncentral absolute moments of are the same.

  29. Because the unconditional Nth central and noncentral do not depend on the probabilities of specific outcomes . Therefore: • Define , where so and

  30. We have: • This form makes explicit an important property frequently observed in security returns: the realized return on a security over a short trading interval will be completely dominated by its unanticipated. • However , it does not follow that in choosing an optimal portfolio the investor should neglect differences in the expected returns among stocks, because the first and second moments of the returns are of the same order.

  31. Let , where , is a function with bounded third partial derivatives. • Denote by X the known value of , then • We use Taylor’s theorem

  32. Where • For each and every j, • So we have

  33. We can describe the dynamics for • Applying the conditional expectation to both side

  34. Define • So

  35. It is clear that the realized change in F over a very short time interval is completely dominated by the component of the unanticipated change. • We have:

  36. So the conditional moment of and is same. • The co-moments between and is also same

  37. The conditional correlation coefficient per unit time between contemporaneous changes in F and X is • Now we study contribution to the change in F over a finite time interval. • Define

  38. If we define • We have • By construction , and therefore . Therefore , the partial sums form a martingale. • Because , from the Law of Large Numbers for martingales that

  39. We have that for fixed T • Taking the limit we have • So, the cumulative error of the approximation goes to zero with probability one. • Hence, for , we have

  40. Hence the stochastic term will have a negligible effect on the change in over a finite time interval. • By the usual limiting arguments for Riemann integration, we have

  41. So we have • The stochastic differential for F is • There is no difference because the contribution of this stochastic term to the moments of dF over the infinitesimal interval dt is , and over finite intervals it disappears.

  42. Let , we get the stochastic differential for X • Throughout this analysis, the only restrictions on the distribution for where (a) (b) (c) (d)the distribution for is discrete.

  43. Assumption 6: The stochastic process for is a Markov process. • The Assumption 6 can be weakened to say that the conditional probabilities for X depend on only a finite amount of past information.

  44. Therefore , provide that p is a well behaved function of x and t, it will satisfy all the properties previous derived for F(t) • This is a “Kolmogorov backward equation”. • Therefore, subject to boundary condition, the formula completely specifies the transition probability densities for the two price.

  45. The only characteristics of the distribution for the that affect the asymptotic distribution for the security price are the first and second moments. • Hence, in the limit of continuous trading, nothing of economic content is lost by assuming that the are independent and identical.

  46. Define is a random variable • When • When are independent and identically distributed with a zero mean and unit variance, we have is normal distribution.

  47. Then the solution to the “Kolmogorov backward equation” with • We define • When the are independent and distribution standard normal, the process is called a Wiener or Brownian.

  48. Then the dynamics of can be wrote as: • And • The class of continuous-time Markov processes whose dynamics can be written in the two form are call Ito’s processes.

  49. Ito’s lemma: Let be a function define on and take the stochastic integral defined by the two form, then the time-dependent random variable is a stochastic integral and its stochastic differential is: • Where the product of the differentials is defined by the multiplication rules and

  50. If the economic structure to be analyzed is such that Assumption 1-6 obtain and can have only type I outcomes. • Then in continuous-trading model, security-pricing dynamics can always be described by Ito processes with no loss of generality.

More Related