1 / 28

Combinatorial Auctions ( Bidding and Allocation)

Combinatorial Auctions ( Bidding and Allocation). Adapted from Noam Nisan. What is a Combinatorial Auction?. Set of Products: Each customer can bid: $700 for { AND } $1200 for { } OR $8 for { } $6 for { } XOR $30 for { } $3 for { ANY 3}.

cellen
Download Presentation

Combinatorial Auctions ( Bidding and Allocation)

An Image/Link below is provided (as is) to download presentation Download Policy: Content on the Website is provided to you AS IS for your information and personal use and may not be sold / licensed / shared on other websites without getting consent from its author. Content is provided to you AS IS for your information and personal use only. Download presentation by click this link. While downloading, if for some reason you are not able to download a presentation, the publisher may have deleted the file from their server. During download, if you can't get a presentation, the file might be deleted by the publisher.

E N D

Presentation Transcript


  1. CombinatorialAuctions(Bidding and Allocation) Adapted from Noam Nisan

  2. What is a Combinatorial Auction? • Set of Products: • Each customer can bid: $700 for { AND } $1200 for { } OR $8 for { } $6 for { } XOR $30 for { } $3 for {ANY 3}

  3. The Model • m items for sale: X = {x1,…,xm} • n bidders: v1,…,vnEvery vi is a valuation of subsets of X:vi : 2X  R+vi(S ) = how much would I pay for S  X • Bids are handed in sealed envelops. • Auctioneer allocates the items among bidders trying to maximize its revenue:Find n disjoint sets - S1,…,Sn  X s.t. vi(Si) is maximal.

  4. Issues • Bidding • Expressiveness • Simplicity • Allocation • Hardness Results • Approximation Algorithms • Payment • Strategy

  5. Bidding • No Externalitiesv (S ) depends only on S. • Free DisposalS T  v (S )  v (T ) • Normalizationv () = 0

  6. Bidding • Let S and T be disjoint item subsets.We say S and T are: • Complementary, if:v (S T ) > v (S ) + v (T ) • Substitutes, if:v (S T ) < v (S ) + v (T )

  7. Bidding - Examples • The additive valuation • v (S ) = |S | • No substitutabilities and no complementarities. • The single item valuation • Want to buy just one item. • v (S ) = 1 (iff S is not empty) • All items are substitutes of each other. • The K-budget valuation • Want to buy up to K items. • v (S ) = min {K, |S |}

  8. Bidding - Examples • The majority valuation • Want to buy most of the items. • v (S ) = 0 for |S | < m / 2 1 otherwise • Symmetric valuation • Let p1,…,pn be non-negative numbers.v (S ) = j=1…|S| pj • Additive: pj=1 • K-budget: pj= 0 for j > K 1 otherwise • Majority: pj= 1 for j = m/2 0 otherwise

  9. Bidding - Examples • Downward sloping symmetric valuation • A symmetric valuation withp1 p2  …  pn 0 • Is viewed as the “normal” economic case.

  10. Bidding - Asymmetric Examples • The monochromatic valuation • m/2 red items, m/2 blue items. • Want to buy items of just one color. • For S having k reds and l blues,v (S ) = max{k,l } • One-of-each-kind valuation • m/2 pairs of items. • Want to buy just one item from each pair. • For S having k pairs and l singletons (|S |=2k+l),v (S ) = k +l

  11. Bidding Languages • A simple language: • Specify v explicitly as a 2m vector. • Impractical - bids are too big. • Language must allow: • To express any “reasonable” valuation with polynomial (in m) size expressions. • To be computationally easy: given v and S, compute v (S ) in polynomial time. • The applet-language: • Specify v as a computer program. • Doesn’t allow efficient allocation algorithms.

  12. Basic Bidding Languages • Atomic bids • v = (S,p)v (T ) = p if TS 0 otherwise • Can’t represent the additive valuation. • OR bids • v = (S1,p1) OR (S2,p2) OR … OR (Sk,pk) • If Si and Sj are disjoint, v (SiSj) = pi+pj • Can express all bids with no substitutabilities and only them.

  13. Basic Bidding Languages • XOR bids • v = (S1,p1) XOR (S2,p2) XOR … XOR (Sk,pk) • v (S ) = max pi s.t. SSi • Can express all bids. • The additive valuation requires 2m atoms in XOR language but only m atoms in OR language.

  14. OR-of-XOR • v = u1ORu2OR … ORukeach ui is a XOR bid. • The bidder is willing to obtain any number of u-s for the sum of their prices. • Downward sloping bid:[({x1},p1) XOR … XOR ({xm},p1)] OR[({x1},p2) XOR … XOR ({xm},p2)] OR…[({x1},pm) XOR … XOR ({xm},pm)]

  15. OR-of-XOR • Theorem: The monochromatic valuation requires an (2m/2) size OR-of-XOR expression. • Proof: • W.L.O.G. every (S,p) is monochromatic. • p = |S | • Can’t have a blue atom in one clause and a red atom in another. • All atoms must be in one XOR clause. • The additive valuation on m/2 red items requires XOR of 2m/2 atoms.

  16. XOR-of-OR • v = u1XORu2XOR … XORukeach ui is an OR bid. • The bidder is willing to obtain the maximal u. • Monochromatic bid:(OR over all reds) XOR (OR over all blues) • Theorem: Fix K = m/2. The K-budget valuation requires an (2m1/4) size XOR-of-OR expression.

  17. OR/XOR Formulae • Definition: Let v and u be valuations. Then, • (v XOR u)(S) = max{v(S),u(S)} • (v OR u)(S) = max{v(R)+u(T)|RT=, RT=S} • Stronger than OR-of-XOR  XOR-of-OR. E.g.:v = (monochromatic on m/2 items) OR (K-budget on m/2 items)

  18. OR Bids with Phantom Items • OR* bids (Fujishima et al.): Each bidder submits an OR bid whose atoms (S,p) may introduce new (phantom) items. • Phantom items are used to express constraints, e.g.: (S1,p1) XOR (S2,p2) = (S1{g},p1) OR (S2{g},p2) • Theorem: Any OR/XOR formula of size s can be rewritten as an OR* formula of size s and O(s 2) phantom items.

  19. The OR* Language • Theorem: The majority valuation requires at least (mm/2) atoms in the OR* language. • Proof: • (S,p) with p > 0 must have at least m/2 real items. • Every subset of m/2 real items must appear as an atom (possibly with phantom items). • Open problem: Is OR* strictly stronger than OR/XOR? • OR* can express externalities.

  20. Bidding and Computability • Definition 1: A bidding language is polynomially interpretable if there exists a polynomial algorithm receiving a bid b in the language and a subset S as input, and outputs b (S ). • Only Atomic and XOR are polynomially interpretable. • Definition 2: A bidding language is polynomially verifiable if there exists an NP algorithm receiving a bid b in the language, a subset S and a proof w of a lower bound on b (S ).

  21. Allocation • Bids are given in OR*. • Auctioneer can treat them as one OR* bid:{Bi}i=1..n, where Bi=(Si,pi) is an atomic bid. • Algorithmically – no difference between real and phantom items.

  22. SPP - Hardness • SPP – Set Packing Problem • Is equivalent to Max-Clique and Max-Independent-Set with weighted vertices. • Is approximable within O(n/log2n) • Not approximable within n1/2- for any >0. • Not approximable within n1- for any >0, unless NP=ZPP.

  23. Integer Programming • Formalization of the allocation problem:Maximize:i=1…nxipiSubject to:i|jSjxi  1, for each j=1…mxi{0,1} , for each i=1…n • Relaxation to linear programming:xi 0, for each i=1…n

  24. Fractional Auctions • Example: communication lines for saleB1 = ({TA-Paris, Paris-NY, P}, 10)B2 = ({TA-London, London-NY, P}, 10)B1 is 1/3 winning and B2 is 2/3 winning.Can use B1 for a 1/3 of its bandwidth, and B2 – for 2/3 of its bandwidth.

  25. Single Item Prices • An allocation x1,…,xn is supported by single item pricesy1,…,yn if: • For every winning bid (xi=1), pijSiyj • For every losing bid (xi=0), pijSiyj • The allocation is exactly supported if for every winning bid, pi=jSiyj • If every item belongs to some winning bid, it is a full allocation.

  26. Single Item Prices • An auction admits single item prices if it has a full allocation supported by single item prices. • Theorem: An auction admits single item prices The linear program produces {0,1} solutions.Then the supporting prices are the solutions to the dual linear program.

  27. Single Item Prices - Example • Bidder #1: • Bidder #2: ({A},5) XOR ({B},6) ({A,P},5) OR ({B,P},6) ({B},3) • Bidder #1 wins A for 5$.Bidder #2 wins B for 3$. • Supporting prices: A = 2$, B = 3$, P = 3$

  28. Cases Where LP Relaxation Is Optimal • Linear Order BidsThe items can be linearly ordered, G = {g1,…,gm}, such that all bids are for sub-ranges, S = {gk,…,gl}. • Hierarchical BidsAll sets form a nested hierarchy. Every two bids S, T are either disjoint or one contains the other. • OR-of-XORs of Singleton Bids • Single Item Bids • Downward Sloping Symmetric Bids

More Related