1 / 49

Bruno DUPIRE Bloomberg Quantitative Research

Bruno DUPIRE Bloomberg Quantitative Research. Arbitrage, Symmetry and Dominance. NYU Seminar New York 26 February 2004 . Background. REAL WORLD:. MODEL:. anything can happen. stringent assumption. 1 possible price,. infinite number of possible. 1 perfect hedge. prices,.

brooks
Download Presentation

Bruno DUPIRE Bloomberg Quantitative Research

An Image/Link below is provided (as is) to download presentation Download Policy: Content on the Website is provided to you AS IS for your information and personal use and may not be sold / licensed / shared on other websites without getting consent from its author. Content is provided to you AS IS for your information and personal use only. Download presentation by click this link. While downloading, if for some reason you are not able to download a presentation, the publisher may have deleted the file from their server. During download, if you can't get a presentation, the file might be deleted by the publisher.

E N D

Presentation Transcript


  1. Bruno DUPIRE Bloomberg Quantitative Research Arbitrage, Symmetry and Dominance NYU Seminar New York 26 February 2004

  2. Background REAL WORLD: MODEL: anything can happen stringent assumption 1 possible price, infinite number of possible 1 perfect hedge prices, infinite potential loss Can we say anything about option prices and hedges when (almost) all assumptions are relaxed? Dominance

  3. Model free properties Dominance

  4. European profilesnecessary & sufficient conditions on call prices K K1 K2 K1 K2 K3 0 K Dominance

  5. A conundrum Call prices as function of strike are positive decreasing: they converge to a positive value a. Do we necessary have ? • It depends which strategies are admissible! • If all strikes can be traded simultaneously, C has to converge to 0. • If not, no sure gain can be made if a > 0. Dominance

  6. Arbitrage with Infinite trading N Dominance

  7. Quiz Strong smile 80 90 S0 = 100 Put (80) = 10, Put (90) = 11.Arbitrageable? Dominance

  8. 90 80 90 Answer • At first sight: • P(80) < P(90), no put spread arbitrage. • At second sight: • P (90) - (90/80) P (80) is a PF • with final value > 0 and premium < 0. Dominance

  9. European pay-off f(S). What are the non-arbitrageable prices for f? Answer: intersection of convex hull with vertical line f UB arbitrage hedge LB 0 initial cost { arbitrage >0 pay-off arbitrageable price S0 Bounds for European claims If market price < LB : buy f, sell the hedge for LB: S Dominance

  10. non Call price monotonicity Call prices are decreasing with the strike:are they necessarily increasing with the initial spot? NO. counter example 1: counter example 2: martingale 120 25% 110 100 100 100 90 90 80 75% 0 T 0 T Dominance

  11. Call price monotonicity If model is continuous Markov,Calls are increasing with the initial spot (Bergman et al) Take 2 independent paths wx and wy starting from x and y today. (1) wx and wy do not cross. (2) wx and wy cross. y y x x Knowing that they cross, the expectation does not depend on the initial value (Markov property). Dominance

  12. Lookback dominance • Domination of • Portfolio: • Strategy: when a new maximum is reached, i.e. • sell • The IV of the call matches the increment of IV of the product. Dominance

  13. Lookback dominance (2) • More generally for • To minimise the price, solve • thanks to Hardy-Littlewood transform (see Hobson). Dominance

  14. Normal model with no interest rates Dominance

  15. Digitals 1 American Digital = 2 European Digitals Reflected path From reflection principle, Proba (Max0-T > K) = 2 Proba (ST > K) K Brownian path As a hedge, 2 European Digitals meet boundary conditions for the American Digital.If S reaches K, the European digital is worth 0.50. Dominance

  16. Down & out call DOC (K, L) = C (K) - P (2L - K) 60.00 50.00 40.00 30.00 20.00 10.00 2L-K K 0.00 50 60 70 80 90 100 110 120 130 140 150 160 170 -10.00 L -20.00 -30.00 -40.00 The hedge meets boundary conditions.If S reaches L, unwind at 0 cost. Dominance

  17. 20.00 15.00 10.00 5.00 0.00 80 90 100 110 120 130 140 150 160 -5.00 -10.00 -15.00 -20.00 Up & out call UOC (K, L) = C (K) - C (2L - K) - 2 (L - K) Dig (L) The hedge meets boundary conditions for the American Digital.If S reaches L, unwind at 0 cost. Dominance

  18. General Pay-off 20.00 15.00 10.00 5.00 0.00 80 90 100 110 120 130 140 150 160 170 180 -5.00 -10.00 -15.00 -20.00 The hedge must meet boundary conditions, i.e. allow unwind at 0 cost. Dominance

  19. Double knock-out digital 2 symmetry points: infinite reflections 0.02 0.9 0.02 0.01 0.4 0.01 0.00 -0.1 80 90 100 110 120 130 -0.01 -0.01 -0.6 -0.02 -1.1 -0.02 Price & Hedge: infinite series of digitals Dominance

  20. Max option (Max - K)+ = 2 C (K) Pricing: Hedge: when current Max moves from M to M+dM sell 2 call spreads C (M) - C (M+dM), that is 2 dM European Digitals strike M. K Dominance

  21. Extensions Dominance

  22. Extension to other dynamics Principle: symmetric dynamics w.r.t L antisymmetric payoff w.r.t L K 0 L 2L-K No interpretation in terms of hedging portfolio but gives numerical pricing method. Dominance

  23. Extension: double KO 0 K 0 L Dominance

  24. Martingale inequalities Dominance

  25. Cernov • Property: • In financial terms: K K+l • Hedge: • Buy C (K), sell l AmDig (K+ l). • If S reaches K+ l , short 1 stock. Dominance

  26. Tchebitchev • Property: • In financial terms: S0 - a S0 S0 + a Dominance

  27. Jensen’s inequality f E[X] X Dominance

  28. Applications X Dominance

  29. Cauchy-Schwarz • Property: • Let us call: • Which implies: Dominance

  30. A sight of Cauchy-Schwarz Dominance

  31. S0 Cauchy-Schwarz (2) • Call dominated by parabola: • In financial terms: • Hedge: • Short ATM straddle. • Buy a Par + b. Dominance

  32. DOOB • Property: • Hedge at date t with current spot x and current max a: • If x < a do nothing. • If x = a -> a + da sell 4da stocks • total short position: 4 (a + da) stocks. Dominance

  33. Up Crossings • Product: pays U(a,b) number of times the spot crosses the band [a,b] upward. • Dominance: 2 3 1 • Hedge: • Buy 1/(b-a) calls strike a. • First time b is reached, short 1/(b-a) stocks. • Then first time a is reached, buy 1/(b-a) stocks. • etc. Dominance

  34. Lookback squared • Property: (£ if S not continuous) • In financial terms: (Parabola centered on S0) • Zero cost strategy: when a new minimum is lowered by dm, buy 2 dm stocks. • At maturity: long 2 (S0-min) stocks paid in average (1/2) (S0+min). • Final wealth: Dominance

  35. A simple inequality Dominance

  36. Quadratic variation Strategy: be long 2xi stock at time ti In continuous time: Dominance

  37. Quadratic variation: application Volatility swap: to lock (historical volatility)2 ~ QV (normal convention) 1) Buy calls and puts of all strikes to create the profile ST2 2) Delta hedge (independently of any volatility assumption) by holding at any time -2St stocks Dominance

  38. Dominance We have quite a few examples of the situation for any martingale measure, which can be interpreted financially as a portfolio dominance result. Is it a general result? ; i.e. if you sell A, can you cover yourself whatever happens by buying B and delta-hedge? The answer is YES. Dominance

  39. General result:“Realise your expectations” Theorem: If for any martingale measure Q Then there exists an adapted process H (the delta-hedge) such as for any path w: That is: any product with a positive expected value whatever the martingale model (even incomplete) provides a positive pay-off after hedge. Dominance

  40. H B Sketch of proof Lemma: If any linear functional positive on B is positive on f, then f is in B Proof: B is convex so if by Hahn-Banach Theorem, there is a separating tangent hyperplane H, a linear functional and a real a such that: Dominance

  41. Sketch of proof (2) The lemma tells us: If for any martingale measure Q, then Which concludes the theorem. stoch. int. positive Dominance

  42. Equality case Corollary of theorem: If for any martingale measure Q, Then there exists H adapted such that Proof: apply Theorem to f and -f: Adding up: Dominance

  43. Bounds for derivatives The theorem does not give a constructive procedure: In incomplete markets, some claims do not have a unique price. What are the admissible prices, under the mere assumption of 0 rates (martingale assumption) Dominance

  44. European pay-off f(S). What are the non-arbitrageable prices for f? Answer: intersection of convex hull with vertical line f UB arbitrage hedge LB 0 initial cost { arbitrage >0 pay-off arbitrageable price S0 Bounds for European claims1 date If market price < LB : buy f, sell the hedge for LB: S Dominance

  45. Arbitrage bound for C100 - C200 ( S0=100, ST>0) Example: Call spread 100 50 100 200 ST Dominance

  46. Bounds for n dates Natural idea: intersection of convex hull of g with (0,…,0) vertical line This corresponds to a time deterministic hedge: decide today the hedge at each date independently from spot. Dominance

  47. Bounds n dates (2) Lower bound: Apply recursively the operator A used in the one dimensional case, i.e. define gives the lower bound Dominance

  48. Bounds for path dependent claimscontinuous time • Brownian case: El Karoui-Quenez (95) • Analogous to American option pricing • American: sup on stopping times • Upper bound: sup on martingale measures • In both cases, dynamic programming • For upper bound: Bellman equation Dominance

  49. Conclusion • It is possible to obtain financial proofs / interpretation of many mathematical results • If claim A has a lesser price than claim B under any martingale model, then there is a hedge which allows B to dominate A for each scenario • If a mathematical relationship is violated by the market, there is an arbitrage opportunity. Dominance

More Related