1 / 16

Turning statistics into knowledge: use and misuse of indicators and models

Turning statistics into knowledge: use and misuse of indicators and models. Data Day Geneva May 18th. Modeling: Partial vs General equilibrium The importance of estimation Indices. Modeling: Partial vs General equilibrium The importance of estimation Indices.

avery
Download Presentation

Turning statistics into knowledge: use and misuse of indicators and models

An Image/Link below is provided (as is) to download presentation Download Policy: Content on the Website is provided to you AS IS for your information and personal use and may not be sold / licensed / shared on other websites without getting consent from its author. Content is provided to you AS IS for your information and personal use only. Download presentation by click this link. While downloading, if for some reason you are not able to download a presentation, the publisher may have deleted the file from their server. During download, if you can't get a presentation, the file might be deleted by the publisher.

E N D

Presentation Transcript


  1. Turning statistics into knowledge: use and misuse of indicators and models Data Day Geneva May 18th

  2. Modeling: Partial vs General equilibrium • The importance of estimation • Indices Turning statistics into knowledge

  3. Modeling: Partial vs General equilibrium • The importance of estimation • Indices Turning statistics into knowledge

  4. Modeling: Partial versus General equilibrium Definitions • Partial equilibrium implies that we only consider a few markets at a time and we do not close the models by including all economic interactions across sectors (e.g., SMART, GSIM in WITS or TRITS at the World Bank). • In a general equilibrium setup all markets are simultaneously modeled and interact with each other (e.g., GTAP developed at Purdue University). Turning statistics into knowledge

  5. Why partial equilibrium? Advantages • Minimal data requirement. We can take advantage of rich WITS datasets. Crucial if question is about: • Bolivia or Uruguay and not the “Rest of South America” • Soya exports and not “Other cereals” • Results of the trade model will feed poverty analysis. Households produce corn or soya, not “cereals”. Heterogeneity of impacts may be lost in a more aggregate general equilibrium model. Turning statistics into knowledge

  6. Why partial equilibrium? More Advantages • Allows analysis of Doha negotiations more accurately: • In the WTO countries negotiate bound tariffs, not applied (tariff “overhang” in many regions) • Applied and bound tariffs are very different within HS 10 Cereals. General equilibrium approach will miss this. Turning statistics into knowledge

  7. Why partial equilibrium? More Advantages • Transparency • Modeling is straightforward and results can be easily explain. No “black box”. • Easy to implement • Excel sheet/SMART/GSIM • Solves aggregation bias Turning statistics into knowledge

  8. Adding apples and oranges…. P Pw+ta Pw+Ta Pw+Tf Pw Q Apples Oranges Fruits • No welfare cost associated with Ta: apples import demand is perfectly inelastic. No tariff on oranges. So no welfare cost associated with fruit protection. • Aggregation bias suggests welfare loss = Turning statistics into knowledge

  9. Why partial equilibrium? Disadvantages • One has information only on a pre-determined number of economic variables (“partial” model of the economy) • One may miss important feedbacks • E.g., Labor market constraints. (But if you know they are there you can model them) • Can be very sensitive to a few (badly estimated) elasticities. Turning statistics into knowledge

  10. Modeling: Partial vs General equilibrium • The importance of estimation • Indices Turning statistics into knowledge

  11. The importance of estimation Ex-post • One can estimate the impact of a certain policy reform on exports, trade creation, diversion, GDP growth, productivity and with a bit of modeling utility (e.g., gravity equation) Ex-ante • One should estimate the critical parameters of the modeling exercise (elasticities, economies of scale, etc..). Otherwise: • Harris (1984) versus Head and Ries (1999) • World Bank (2001) versus Hoekman et al (2004) • GEP(2001) versus common sense • Importance of comparing relative and not absolute results Turning statistics into knowledge

  12. But why do simulation results differ? • Scenarios are not the same • Full versus partial • Different base years (benchmarks) • Mixing with other reforms (fiscal policy, trade facilitation) • Data are not the same • GTAP data is standard, but PTAs, NTBs.. • Parameters (elasticities) are not the same • Modeling assumptions differ • Perfect versus imperfect competition • Flexible versus rigid labor markets • Endogeneity of TFP to trade openness Turning statistics into knowledge

  13. Modeling: Partial vs General equilibrium • The importance of estimation • Indices Turning statistics into knowledge

  14. Indices: between analysis and narrative • According to statisticians: “what cannot be counted does not count”, but “do indicators try to count what cannot be counted”? • Composite indices are good for: • Narrative • And advocacy of particular reform/policy • Decision making process if based on policies rather than outcomes, and aggregated using a proper technique. Turning statistics into knowledge

  15. Indices Problems: • Modeling versus estimation of weights of different components (or subjective versus objective criteria) • Based on theory, not hand-waving (World Bank’s OTRI versus IMF’s old TRI) • Rankings and the importance of measurement error (OTRI versus TRI or Doing Business) Turning statistics into knowledge

  16. Concluding remarks • Keep it simple and transparent • Don’t trust your guts: estimate everything you can! • Pay attention to measurement error • Compare relative policy shocks not absolute numbers Turning statistics into knowledge

More Related