Monopoly
Download
1 / 30

Monopoly Here we see what a monopoly is and its revenue potential. - PowerPoint PPT Presentation


  • 442 Views
  • Uploaded on

Monopoly Here we see what a monopoly is and its revenue potential. Overview Monopoly means one seller. In perfect competition many sellers were price takers. Any one seller could not influence the price of the product in the market. The competitive firm could only choose what amount to sell.

loader
I am the owner, or an agent authorized to act on behalf of the owner, of the copyrighted work described.
capcha
Download Presentation

PowerPoint Slideshow about 'Monopoly Here we see what a monopoly is and its revenue potential.' - andrew


An Image/Link below is provided (as is) to download presentation

Download Policy: Content on the Website is provided to you AS IS for your information and personal use and may not be sold / licensed / shared on other websites without getting consent from its author.While downloading, if for some reason you are not able to download a presentation, the publisher may have deleted the file from their server.


- - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - E N D - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - -
Presentation Transcript
Monopoly l.jpg

Monopoly

Here we see what a monopoly is and its revenue potential.


Overview l.jpg
Overview

Monopoly means one seller.

In perfect competition many sellers were price takers. Any one seller could not influence the price of the product in the market. The competitive firm could only choose what amount to sell.

A monopoly firm will have to determine both how much to sell and at what price. Let’s look at these ideas a little more on the following few slides.


Slide3 l.jpg

p

Review

D

Market Q

In a market, consumers as a group are thought to want to buy a greater quantity the lower the price. We see this as a downward sloping demand curve.


Review l.jpg

p $

Review

S

p*

P=MR=D

D

Market Q Firm Q

In a competitive market, the market demand from consumers interacts with market supply from many sellers and we get an equilibrium price, like p* in the graph. At this point, since any one firm is a small part of the market, when we look at a firm it is a price taker. Thus, when the firm thinks about selling another unit it can sell that unit at the same price as the previous unit and thus MR = P for a competitive firm.


Slide5 l.jpg

Analogy: To think about the marginal revenue for a competitive firm I like to think about a pop machine. Say the price of a pop is $1.25.

Say the machine has been refilled and the pops are not chilled to perfection and you are the first one to make a purchase. What is the total revenue in the machine after you make your purchase? $1.25! Since the total revenue was zero before you bought, the change in total revenue from the sale of another unit (in this case the first one), was $1.25. This is exactly what we mean by marginal revenue. Marginal revenue is the change in total revenue from changing output by 1 unit.

Now say I buy a pop right after you. The total revenue in the machine is 1.25(2) = 2.50 and the marginal revenue is 1.25.

SO, MR = P for a competitive firm.


Monopoly6 l.jpg
Monopoly competitive firm I like to think about a pop machine. Say the price of a pop is $1.25.

For a monopoly firm the demand is the same as the

market demand we see in competition. The demand is

downward sloping to the right, what is called less than

perfectly elastic.

Since the monopolist is the only seller, it is natural they

face the market demand curve.

The situation of monopoly is often called imperfect

competition.


Sources of monopoly l.jpg
Sources of monopoly competitive firm I like to think about a pop machine. Say the price of a pop is $1.25.

1) Exclusive control of an input – deBeers is an example

2) Economies of scale – the case of a natural monopoly. The idea here is that AC can be pushed really low by one firm and it then makes sense for only one firm to serve the market.

3) Patents – protecting inventions for a time may give monopoly power.

4) Network economies – Microsoft Windows is an example of the idea – once enough people use a product sometimes using another type of product becomes less functional.

5) Granted by government


Maximize profit l.jpg
Maximize profit competitive firm I like to think about a pop machine. Say the price of a pop is $1.25.

Since the monopolist is the only seller in the market,

the monopolist must decide 1) what price to charge and

2) how much to sell.

When the monopolist sells, she is worried about profit. The goal is to maximize profit. But, in order to maximize

profit, the pattern of revenues and costs at various output levels must be understood. The pattern of cost was the topic of an earlier section. Now we look at the pattern of revenue.


Slide9 l.jpg

p competitive firm I like to think about a pop machine. Say the price of a pop is $1.25.

Monopoly

6

5

D

2 3

Market Q

Here the monopoly is the only firm in the market. When the price is 6, in this example the consumers want 2 units. Total revenue would be 12. But, this firm, if it wants to sell 3 units has to lower the price on all units to 5. The competitive firm didn’t have to worry about another price like the monopoly firm.


Monopoly marginal revenue l.jpg
Monopoly – marginal revenue competitive firm I like to think about a pop machine. Say the price of a pop is $1.25.

So, because the way consumers are in this example on the previous screen, when P = 6, 2 units will be sold and when the P = 5, 3 units will be sold. Total revenue would move from 12 to 15 when the quantity moves from 2 to 3.

So, the additional revenue from the 3rd unit is $3. This is the marginal revenue of the 3rd unit.

Note, the price to get the third unit sold is $5, but the marginal revenue is only $3.

SO, P>MR at a quantity.


Interpretation l.jpg
Interpretation competitive firm I like to think about a pop machine. Say the price of a pop is $1.25.

When the price is lowered from 6 to 5 the amount sold rises. In fact, the 3rd unit sold brings in 5 in revenue. But this isn’t all we need to look at to have MR. Since the monopolist must sell to all consumers at the same price, the first 2 units now get sold at 5 as well. That means revenue on those 2 units will not include $6 per unit when the price is lowered.

Continuing with the example,

MR(of the 3rd unit) = 5 - (6-5) 2

= 3


Interpretation12 l.jpg
interpretation competitive firm I like to think about a pop machine. Say the price of a pop is $1.25.

P

6

area c is the gain in

revenue from selling

more

area a is the loss in

revenue from selling

at a lower price.

a

5

b

c

Q

2

3

Area a + b = 6 times 2= 12 = TR when P = 6

Area b + c = 5 times 3 = 15 = TR when P = 5

MR = c - a = 5 - 2 = 3


Let s do another example l.jpg
Let’s do another example competitive firm I like to think about a pop machine. Say the price of a pop is $1.25.

P Q

5 0

4 1

3 2

2 3

1 4

0 5

Say this is the demand from consumers in the market. If the price is 5 consumers want nothing, for instance. Let’s put TR on the next slide.


Slide14 l.jpg

Let’s do another example competitive firm I like to think about a pop machine. Say the price of a pop is $1.25.

P Q TR

5 0 0

4 1 4

3 2 6

2 3 6

1 4 4

0 5 0

Total revenue is just P times Q, so you should check what I have here.

Next let’s add MR to the table.


Slide15 l.jpg

Let’s do another example competitive firm I like to think about a pop machine. Say the price of a pop is $1.25.

P Q TR MR

5 0 0 ----

4 1 4 4

3 2 6 2

2 3 6 0

1 4 4 -2

0 5 0 -4

MR, marginal revenue, is the change in TR when we add a unit of output. Note at Q = 0 I have the line --- because we have not had a change yet.

The MR = 4 for a Q = 1 because TR went from 0 to 4 when Q went from 0 to 4. The MR = 2 for Q = 2 because TR went from 4 to 6 when Q went from 1 to 2.

Note: MR can become negative, in theory. Also note that P > MR at each Q (except Q = 1, but we usually ignore this.)


Mr from areas to height l.jpg
MR from areas to height competitive firm I like to think about a pop machine. Say the price of a pop is $1.25.

P

In the above diagram we think of

MR as area c - a and we get a

number.

a

In the bottom graph we

can think of the number

as a height. Note still the

MR is lower than the price

on the demand curve.

On the next screen we

will see the whole MR

curve.

D

b

c

Q

P

height = MR

D

Q


Monopoly mr in a graph l.jpg
Monopoly MR in a graph competitive firm I like to think about a pop machine. Say the price of a pop is $1.25.

$

I do not have a proof

for you, but you can

see in this diagram

that MR is also a

straight line that starts

at the same place as

demand in the upper

left, but is always

below demand because

P>MR. Like at Q = 3,

MR = 3 and P = 5.

5

3

D

Q

3

Note that a good way to draw in MR is to first draw demand and then put MR through the Q axis halfway out to the demand curve. I put an X at that point.


Monopoly pricing and output l.jpg

Monopoly Pricing and Output competitive firm I like to think about a pop machine. Say the price of a pop is $1.25.

We study the pricing and output decision of the monopoly firm.


Price and output decision for the monopolist in the short run l.jpg
Price and output decision for the monopolist in the short run

The amount of output the monopolist should sell in the

short run is the amount where MR = MC(as long as

P>AVC), just as in the case of the competitive firm.

The price charged would then be the price on the

demand curve above the quantity where MR = MC.

(recall P = MR for firms in comp, but P>MR for the monopolpy firm.)


Logic of mr mc rule l.jpg
Logic of MR = MC rule run

$

The Q = b is the Q where

MR = MC. But look at Q = a. At

that point, Q could be increased

and more would be added to

revenue than to cost and thus

profit would rise. We know this

because the MR > MC for these

Q (Compare the heights of the curves).

MC

D

Q

a b c

MR

Now let’s look at a Q greater than where MR = MC, like at point c. More has been added to cost than to revenue and thus profit would fall. We know this because MC > MR at this Q.


What price l.jpg
What price? run

$

MC

At Q*, where MR = MC, P* is the price on the demand curve

consumers are willing to pay for Q* and thus this is the price charged by the monopolist.

P*

D

Q

Q*

MR


Qualification l.jpg
Qualification run

ATC = .12

$

ATC

Note that the ATC

is above the demand

curve, so the firm

will lose money. In

the short run, the

question is whether

the firm should

shutdown or

continue to operate.

Let’s go to the next

screen and say more

about this.

MC

AVC1

=.11

AVC1

AVC2

P*= .10

AVC2

= .08

D

20

MR


Continue l.jpg
continue run

Note that the Q where MR = MC = 20. So, if the firm operates at all it should make 20.

Note at Q = 20, the price on the demand curve is .10 but the ATC = .12

Now, remember ATC = TC/Q so ATC times Q = TC.

TR = P Q = .1(20) = 2

TC = ATC Q = .12(20) = 2.4

Profit = TR – TC = 2 – 2.4 = - .4

Or

Profit = (P – ATC)Q = (1 - .12)20 = -.4 The firm is losing money.


Continue 2 l.jpg
continue 2 run

If the AVC curve is AVC2 for the firm then at Q = 20 the AVC = .08. This means the TVC = AVC Q = .08(20) = 1.6.

Thus the TR = 2 can cover the 1.6 of TVC and what is left of TR, .4 can go to paying some of the total fixed costs. If the firm shuts down it would have nothing going to fixed cost. So the firm should operate.

Thus, operate if at the Q where MR = MC the P > AVC.

Note if the AVC is AVC 1 = .11 the P < AVC. The firm should shut down. TR of 2 falls short of TVC of 2.2 and covers none of fixed while if the firm shuts down it only has to cover the fixed cost.


Quiz 1 not a real quiz l.jpg
Quiz 1 – not a real quiz run

$

MC

Is this monopoly firm

earning a profit? If so,

draw in the graph the

rectangle that

represents the profit.

ATC

P*

D

Q*

MR


Quiz 2 not a real quiz l.jpg
Quiz 2 not a real quiz run

$

MC

ATC

Is it possible for a

monopoly to lose

money?

Indicate in the graph

how much this

monopoly is losing by

indicating the loss

rectangle.

AVC

P*

D

Q*

MR


Slide27 l.jpg

Is a monopoly guaranteed a profit. I have a monopoly – I make a pizza fork (not really, but listen up). Look at the palm of your right hand, thumb up. When you wrap your hand around the fork your thumb is next to a button on the fork (sorry, only right handed version.). When you press the button

Thumb

Palm of hand

A razor blade edge comes out here and you move your hand so your thumb is now pointing left and you cut your pizza real easily.

The demand for my item is much lower than where my costs are.


Slide28 l.jpg

Can Monopolies charge whatever price they want? The answer is yes, but with a qualification.

Remember consumers have a demand for the product and have prices they are willing to pay. As long as the monopoly is charging a price the consumers are willing to pay then they can charge whatever they like. But if the monopoly charges too high a price consumers will not buy at all.

OUR ECONOMIC RULE – sell Q where MR = MC, charge the price on the demand curve above this Q (So charge whatever you want but to profit max charge this one) and both of these ideas are dependent on the P>AVC at this Q.


The monopoly solution and elasticity l.jpg
The monopoly solution and elasticity is yes, but with a qualification.

Without proof I tell you that with a given demand curve and MR curve for the monopoly, we have

MR = P (1 – F), where F = 1/absolute value of elasticity of demand.

Recall that elasticity of demand changes as we move down the demand curve (in absolute value the number gets smaller).

Monopoly mark-up

We see the monopoly has P > MC at its profit maximizing level of output. So the mark-up of P over MC as a percentage of the price is (P – MC)/P.


Mark up and elasticity l.jpg
Mark-up and elasticity is yes, but with a qualification.

The mark-up again is (P – MC)/P.

The profit maximization condition was MR = MC.

The MR, elasticity connection was MR = P(1 – F) = P - PF.

SO, the mark-up can be changed to

(P – MC)/P = (P – MR)/P = (P –(P – PF))/P = (P – P + PF)/P

= PF/P = 1/absolute value of elasticity of demand.

The monopoly mark-up is a function of the elasticity of demand. Note that since we have absolute value of elasticity, the mark-up is a positive number, and since P>MC, 1/abs <1, or abs>1. This means the elasticity of demand will be in the elastic range for a monopoly.


ad